Must be 2-3 pages and you must use the company Capital One
8-2: Sustainability Assessment, answer the following questions regarding the company you have chosen to investigate:
Does your company do business with sustainability and the global village in mind?
How does your company meet the standards put forth in the readings and articles?
What has been your experience?
How do the countries to which companies expand respond?
Cite at least two sources.
Global governance and the interface with
business: new institutions, processes and
partnerships
Partnered governance: aligning corporate
responsibility and public policy in the global
economy
Atle Midttun
Abstract
Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to note the remarkable expansion of corporate social
responsibility (CSR) throughout the late 1990s and early 2000s. Taking this as point of departure, it aims
to discuss the potential for aligning CSR-oriented industrial self-regulation with public governance to fill
some of the governance gap in the
global economy.
Design/methodology/approach – The paper provides a conceptual discussion, empirically
underpinned by three case studies.
Findings – The paper finds that it is plausible, and empirically supported by the case studies, to
conceive of a considerable role for CSR based self-regulation in the global economy. A central
precondition is the ability of civil society organizations to establish ‘‘moral rights’’ as credible voices for
‘‘just causes’’ in a media-driven communicative society, and thereby put pressure on brand sensitive
industry. The paper finds that corporate self-regulation may fill a larger part of the governance gap if
public policy is oriented to engage with industry in a partnered mode.
Research limitations/implications – The paper establishes a conceptual base for exploring the
governance implications of CSR, casuistically underpinned by three case studies. Further studies are
needed, however, to explore the scale and scope of partnered governance in the global economy.
Practical implications – The paper provides insights into an approach to increase governability of the
global economy.
Originality/value – The originality of the paper lies in exploring the implications of CSR for governance,
and for highlighting how the governance potential may be enhanced by reorientation of public policy.
Keywords Governance, Corporate social responsibility, Globalization, Regulation
Paper type Conceptual paper
Introduction
The late twentieth and the early twenty-first centuries have seen increasing economic
globalization in the form of both globally extended capital markets and extended
outsourcing of production in global supply systems across the world. After three decades of
predominant liberalist orientation, the international economy remains strongly
pro-commercially biased.
International governance of social and environmental concerns has been relatively much
weaker, reflecting the lack of resourceful engagement by committed powerful actors and
PAGE 406 j CORPORATE GOVERNANCE j VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008, pp. 406-418, Q Emerald Group Publishing Limited, ISSN 1472-0701 DOI 10.1108/14720700810899158
Atle Midttun is based at the
Norwegian School of
Management, Oslo,
Norway.
The author is grateful to the
Research Council of Norway for
support to this article under the
projects ‘‘C(S)R in Global Value
Chains’’ and ‘‘Sustainability for
the 21st Century: Overcoming
Limitations to Creative
Adaptation in Addressing the
Climate Challenge’’. The author
also wishes to thank Nina
Witoszek at the Centre for
Development and the
Environment at the University of
Oslo, for valuable comments.
pressure from self-interested nation states. We are, in other words, faced with a highly
imbalanced globalization, where, judging by the standards of advanced democratic
industrial economies, the global space remains politically under-governed – particularly in
the environmental and social fields.
Yet while the global markets remain politically under-governed in a political sense (Vig and
Axelrod, 1999), CSR and business self-regulation have rapidly expanded. With 45 million
hits on Google (Google, 15 April 2007), corporate social responsibility (CSR) has grown to
become a megatrend that is expanding on most continents (Figure 1). From the US,
Australia and New Zealand and later on in Europe, CSR has spread to Africa and Asia, as
illustrated by the number of press articles on the topic.
Following this remarkable expansion, substantive literature has developed to explore the
business case for CSR, arguing how CSR might enhance conflict management, facilitate
reputation building, stimulate the development of industrial clusters, support risk
management etc. (see for instance Elkington, 2001; Fombrun, 1996; Hart, 1997; Porter
and Kramer, 2002, 2006; Midtun and Gautesen, 2005; Midttun et al., 2006). However, given
that CSR contributes to social and environmental responsibility, there should also be a public
policy case for CSR, especially for advanced welfare nations. They largely fail to impose
what they see as acceptable social and environmental standards on the global economy
through conventional regulation. Systematic analysis of the public policy case for CSR,
however, is largely lacking. This article attempts to fill the gap by highlighting the potential for
and characteristics of CSR-oriented public governance based on a partnered mode.
Legitimate ‘‘moral rights’’ in a communicative society
A major factor behind the booming CSR is the strong engagement by civil society
organizations (CSOs). CSR that is driven by CSOs is strongly coupled to stakeholdership, an
important mantra in business strategy since the mid-1980s, inducing the modern
stakeholder-oriented firm to engage in dialogue with interested parties that are affected
by the firm or that may affect it (Freeman, 1984).
In modern media-driven societies, idealistic stakeholders acquire bargaining power
vis-à-vis industry through public legitimacy bestowed upon them by media in open public
debate. When seen as credible voices for ‘‘just causes’’, they come to represent what
Rousseau (1988) called the ‘‘volonté general’’ or general will with the moral right to stand up
against formal authority – be it the firm or the state. It is suggested in this paper that such
‘‘moral rights’’ bestowed upon CSOs through media ‘‘canonization’’ may carry extensive
weight in a brand-oriented commercial context where negative media exposure could inflict
serious brand damage. Stakeholders with communicatively consolidated legitimate ‘‘moral
rights’’ may, therefore, sometimes negotiate almost on par with holders of property rights.
Figure 1 Corporate social responsibility in international press
VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008 jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj PAGE 407
The stakeholder model based on legitimate ‘‘moral rights’’ could thus represent an efficient
internalization of social and environmental externalities such as pollution and workers’ rights.
Because it is backed by strong agency, morality-driven and media-supported CSOs most
often have greater effects than direct customer-driven CSR. CSOs have strong incentives to
pursue their just cause actively. This is what their business model is set up for, and what their
existence ultimately depends on.
‘‘Moral rights’’-based stakeholder bargaining has many similarities with Nobel prize winner
Ronald Coase’s concept of self-regulation through bilateral negotiation (Coase, 1960). The
so-called Coase theorem assumes that individual property holders can also be endowed
with rights to natural resources, and may subsequently negotiate adequate restrictions on
negative spillovers from industry without public regulation beyond a privately enforceable
legal framework. However, the collective action problems with respect to establishing
‘‘Coasian’’ property rights over natural resources and the problem of dealing with the
tremendous transaction costs associated with asserting them on an individual basis remain
overwhelming.
In this respect, the ‘‘moral rights’’-based stakeholder model remains much more operative,
at least in democratic countries, with respect to both establishing rights and enforcing social
and environmental concerns into business operations. When they engage in the global
arena, even non-democratic countries are vulnerable to this type of pressure.
Business-led CSR along two trajectories
The moral challenge by CSOs and other stakeholders has resulted in two trajectories in
business-led CSR (Figure 2). One trajectory involves making CSR part of a corporate
differentiation strategy where leading firms have taken CSR successively into their strategic
core, while in another trajectory CSR has been successively internalized into industrial
standards in the attempt to lift the social and environmental performance of whole sectors of
the economy. In both cases this contributes to internalizing environmental and social
concerns into industrial
practice.
The differentiation strategy, as described in CSR literature, has evolved in several stages
(Figure 2). Particularly in the US there has been a strong tradition for philanthropy, which was
Figure 2 Trajectories in business-led CSR
PAGE 408jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008
often fairly unrelated to core business. Porter and Kramer (2002, 2006) have argued for
relating philanthropy closer to core business to achieve synergies between CSR and
business engagement. A further step towards CSR-differentiated business strategy has
been to engage in CSR as part of a supportive strategy. Car manufacturers developing
green niche vehicles alongside their dominant combustion-driven mainstream cars are good
examples. The final step is to merge CSR into the core business strategy in order to build a
unique business model for the firm. An illustration of this is energy companies that engage
exclusively or dominantly in renewable technologies and link their business strategy to
sustainable development and climate change.
The introduction of CSR into industrial standards has also evolved in stages (Figure 2). It has
typically started with ad hoc reactions to CSO challenges, often followed by CSO-led
engagements in sector-specific environmental and/or social accounting. Taken further, this
process leads to the consolidation of industrial guidelines and in some cases of standards.
Even when backed by third party verification, such standards may take on serious
performance implications. Finally, standards may eventually gain political endorsement and
thereby take on a quasi-legal character or a de facto rule system (Burns and Flam, 1987).
From industry-led CSR to partnered governance
Seen from a public governance point-of-view, there has long been a growing concern about
the increasing economic and technological interdependence and the remaining
fragmentation of international political decision-making. Public policy analysis has varied,
however, from the neo-realist school, that sees the world system as an inherently anarchic
set of relations among sovereign nation states (Baylis and Smith, 2005) to economic
globalists that see markets as self-regulating entities (Martinelli, 2007).
The arguments advanced on a wave of neo-liberalism for shifting ever larger parts of the
economy into a competitive market-based mode of operation (Kahn, 1988; Ogus, 2001)
were also often phrased in a rhetoric that milsleadingly implied that strong political
governance could easily be transferred from the context of domestic regulation in advanced
industrial nations onto the global arena. These optimistic liberal-institutionalist confidence in
international organizations and regimes (Baylis and Smith, 2005) has at best only
contributed moderately to global governance, and primarily in the commercial rather than in
the environmental and social fields.
Seen in a governance perspective, CSR represents a form of self-regulation that may
supplement, or even to some extent substitute, public policy-led governance. However, we
argue that CSR-based self-regulation could be much more effective if it is was more
systematically integrated with political steering in joint partnered governance.
Partnered governance – a conceptual framing
Conceptually, partnered governance and its interfaces with political/regulatory governance
and industrial self-regulation may be graphically displayed in a two-dimensional matrix.
Policy-driven governance, with the traditional de-regulation debate of planned versus
market economy, is displayed in the upper part of Figure 3 (quadrants I and II) representing
along the horizontal axis both planned economic and regulated market-based governance
forms (Midttun, 1998).
The lower part of Figure 3 (quadrants III and IV) represents the space where the strong
governance assumptions do not hold. This domain is largely left to CSR-based industrial
self-regulation. As already mentioned, this self-regulation also comes in an individually
differentiated and a collectively industrially standardized form.
Partnered governance constitutes a middle ground where the two spheres potentially
interface. This paper suggests that by forming this interface adequately, through both
complementary policy strategies and complementary policy tools, it is possible to enhance
governance of the global economy.
In order to engage efficiently in partnered governance, governments need to engage
beyond traditional roles. As argued by Fox et al. (2002), they need to move out of traditional
VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008 jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj PAGE 409
mandating strategies based on command and control legislation to facilitating, partnering
and endorsing strategies (Table I).
In the facilitating role, public authorities may stimulate industrial action by, for instance,
developing or supporting appropriate CSR management tools and mechanisms, including
voluntary product labeling schemes, benchmarks and guidelines for company management
systems and reporting, thereby supporting self-regulatory initiatives. A government may
also facilitate CSR-orientation by creating fiscal incentives through its own procurement and
investment practice.
In the partnering role, governments may bring in complementary competencies and
resources to tackle social and environmental issues outside their unilateral authoritative
control. By acting as participants, conveners or facilitators, governments may stimulate
complementary self-regulatory engagement and thereby achieve effects that go far beyond
what they might have achieved through unilateral action when operating under conditions of
limited authoritative control.
Finally, governments may engage in endorsement through the effects of public procurement
or public sector management practices or through direct recognition of the efforts of
individual enterprises by award schemes.
Creative government strategies in a partnered governance mode would increase the payoff
for societal concerns into business strategy and elicit complementary industrial
engagement with a potential to shape a more ‘‘civil’’ global capitalism, somewhat
Table I Government roles
Mandating ‘‘Command and control’’ legislation Regulators and inspectorates Legal and fiscal penalties and rewards
Facilitating Enabling legislation Creating incentives Capacity building
Funding support Raising awareness Stimulating markets
Partnering Combining resources Stakeholder engagement Dialogue
Endorsing Political support Publicity and praise
Source: Fox et al. (2002)
Figure 3 Partnered governance
PAGE 410jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008
analogous to the negotiated political economy in advanced welfare states (Schmitter and
Streeck, 1985).
Case illustrations
The following examples show partnered governance in three different configurations
illustrating some of the variety in this field: regulatory competition between NGOs and
industrial regulation in forestry; new modes of industry-policy collaboration in the extractive
industries’ transparency initiative; and the crossover between public policy and industrial
implementation in the ethical trading initiative. In all the cases, CSR initiatives have come in
response to challenges voiced in the public arena, but also in some cases supplemented by
direct pressure from industrial contractors, resulting in various forms of what Ayres and
Braithwaite (1995) have termed responsive regulation. The interface between industrial CSR
and public governance differs, however, from case to case.
Partnered governance under regulatory competition in the forest and paper and pulp
industry
Partnered governance intervention in the forestry and paper and pulp industry has arisen in
response to challenges to traditional business practices in the media and to public debate
on issues ranging from environmental topics such as biodiversity and certification of timber
to human rights and corruption.
A characteristic feature of the new regulatory initiatives within the forest and paper and pulp
industry is the competition between NGOs and industrial interests. Faced with ambitious
NGO initiatives, the industry association has sought to develop an alternative standard for
self-regulation, while individual firms have bowed to overwhelming societal pressure and
chosen the pragmatic option of adapting to both standards selectively.
This case thus highlights how buyer pressure and NGO-driven regulatory initiatives may
trigger government-partnered industrial self-regulation to enhance improved environmental
and social performance.
Evolution of the regulatory initiative
The NGO initiative to establish the Forest Stewardship Council (FSC) and its offer of
certification of sustainable and ecologically-sound forestry was partially driven by the failure
of an intergovernmental process to agree on a global forest compact. Established in 1993
(FSC, 2006) to drive forward an agenda for sustainable forestry, the FSC developed a set of
principles and criteria for forest management that address legal issues, indigenous rights,
labor rights, multiple benefits and environmental impacts relating to forest management
(FSC, 2006).
The scheme met with critical opposition from leading forest industry groups, often in alliance
with host/home governments. Although they shared some basic ecological concerns with
the FSC, in their view the FSC was making unrealistic demands that would impede efficient
forestry practices. In close collaboration with home-base governments, the forest industry
responded with a set of CSR-based regulatory initiatives to establish more ‘‘realistic’’
standards for sustainable forestry.
In North America, the Sustainable Forest Initiative (SFI) program was adopted by the trade
association for wood, paper and wood products (AF&PA).
The European Program for the Endorsement of Forest Certification schemes (PEFC) was
established in 1999 as an umbrella organization for certification, in close cooperation with
national legal systems.
The differing origins and objectives of each scheme have led to differences not only in the
contents of the standards but also in the administration of the rule systems. As noted by
Olivier (2006), the SFI program relies on certifiers whose independence and professional
competence is assessed through the existing US national accreditation system, whereas the
FSC has an internal accreditation process designed to operate under the jurisdiction of the
FSC Board of Directors. In line with the emphasis by the FSC on rewarding exemplary
VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008 jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj PAGE 411
forestry in the market place, it has more explicit restrictions on intensive management,
plantations and genetically modified crops (GMCs).
Leading firms in the forest and wood processing industry have generally taken a pragmatic
position on extra-legal regulation. They relate to both NGO and government-partnered
industry standards and seek to bridge the span between ideals and reality by flagging
adherence in principle but adopting pragmatic adjustment and gradual implementation in
practice.
Discussion
As previously mentioned, a characteristic feature of the new regulatory initiatives within the
forest and paper and pulp industry is the competition between NGOs and industrial
interests. As noted by Olivier (2006), competing regulatory initiatives ultimately arise from
the political differences that separate environmental groups from forest owners and
industrial organizations. The green movement tends to regard certification as a mechanism
to reward (through continued market access) only the very best forest management and to
promote an ideal of forest management that mimics natural processes and preserves
so-called old growth. They promote a vision of a single, internationally harmonized system of
forest certification requiring forest owners to comply with very high standards of forestry
performance. This is essentially the approach adopted by the FSC.
In contrast, Olivier (2006) notes that industry and forest owner groups in partnership with
host governments tend to regard certification as a mechanism to promote progressive,
step-wise improvement in forest management. They also believe certification should provide
an effective marketing tool to promote the environmental benefits of wood. The PFEC, for
instance, represents government and industry positions and a gradualist approach,
including national industrial initiatives that seek to codify extra-legal rule-making adapted to
local conditions.
The regulatory competition has, therefore, most likely produced higher level regulation or
higher levels of environmental and social quality in the forest industry than under
conventional authoritative regulation in the current global economy, one of the reasons being
that producer countries have been disciplined by commercial buyers abroad and NGOs.
Partnered governance in upstream petroleum industry: the extractive industries’
transparency initiative
New partnered governance initiatives have been launched in the extractive industries to
meet the challenges to traditional regulation and business practices – particularly at the
interface between multinational petroleum companies and resource-rich developing states.
To quote the Financial Times (2005):
Extractive industries have long been criticised for perpetuating the ‘resource curse’ – distorting
the economy and propping up corrupt and autocratic governments that exploit their control of the
revenues to keep themselves in power.
This was the immediate background for the Extractive Industries’ Transparency Initiative
(EITI), launched in 2002 in Johannesburg at the World Summit on Sustainable Development.
The initiative aimed to promote greater transparency around the large-scale money transfers
taking place in the petroleum and mining sectors (EITI, 2006).
Core focus
This case highlights how the EITI weaves several modes of governance into a powerful web
of partnered governance:
B Large western multinational companies are jointly supporting the demand to publish
money streams from their own extractive activity for the treasury in host countries as a
result of strong pressure from interest organizations and public opinion.
B Host countries are taking on obligations to publish the money streams in the public sector,
many as a result of considerable pressure from international organizations such as the
PAGE 412jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008
World Bank, donor countries and others, but also motivated by the need for inner
administrative reform.
B Civil society organizations have been actively promoting the EITI both with the
government of their home countries and with authorities and foreign countries – the latter
often with considerable difficulty.
Financial investors, including many of the large fund managers, have generally taken a more
active attitude to free flow of information, transparent governance and corporate social
responsibility.
Breakthroughs on the issues listed above imply a breakthrough for open information and
responsible economic governance as set out in a number of international conventions.
Evolution of the regulatory initiative
The EITI, initially pioneered by Transparency International and Global Witness, was later
actively promoted by the UK government. It is based on a voluntary agreement aiming to
increase transparency in transactions between governments and companies within the
extractive industries. The UK EITI government initiative followed an unsuccessful
self-regulatory initiative by BP in 2001 to publish unilaterally what they pay in taxes, fees
and signature bonuses in Angola. BP’s initiative was unsuccessful because Sonargol, the
state oil company of Angola, threatened to exclude BP from Angola, and BP subsequently
only published the signature bonus mandatory under UK law.
The EITI received mixed reactions from other western countries and their multinational oil
companies. The US government and US home-based petroleum multinationals such as
Exxon and Texaco would not support the initiative unless they received credible
commitments from oil-rich nations and systematic implementation of the principles by all
companies involved. Other nations, such as Norway, joined the EITI and supported the
initiative both at the government and company level. The two Norwegian petroleum
companies, Statoil and Norsk Hydro, which are in the process of internationalizing their
petroleum engagements beyond the Norwegian Continental shelf, were both developing
advanced CSR programs and were eager to support the initiative.
A significant step towards implementing the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative
(EITI) in the Republic of Azerbaijan was taken on 24 November 2004. The governmental
Committee on EITI, foreign and local extractive industry companies (oil and gas) and the
NGOs’ Coalition for Increasing Transparency in Extractive Industries signed a Memorandum
of Understanding (MOU) for the implementation of EITI in the Republic of Azerbaijan. A total
of 20 foreign and local extractive (oil and gas) industry companies, including the State Oil
Company of the Republic of Azerbaijan, BP, Exxon, Statoil, Total, Lukoil, Unocal, Shell and
Devon Energy have since signed the MOU (State Oil Fund, 2004).
More recently the EITI has attracted support from a number of other resource-rich
developing countries – namely the Republic of Congo, Ghana, the Kyrgyz Republic,
Nigeria, São Tomé e Principe, Timor Leste and Trinidad and Tobago. These countries have
begun to interpret and implement the principles, thus playing a pivotal role in shaping the
EITI. The engagement of resource-rich developing countries has also brought the US
multinationals and the US government onboard. In parallel, however, some NGOs – such as
Global Witness – are calling for stronger mandatory engagement.
The reception of the EITI in the business community has been rather mixed, ranging from
positive embracement by petroleum companies with headquarters in North Western Europe
to more reluctant conditional acceptance by those with headquarters in the USA.
The EITI has also gained broader industrial support outside the petroleum industry. In June
2003, the ‘‘Investors’ Statement on Transparency in the Extractives Sector’’ in support of the
EITI was signed by 38 investors. The process was led by ISIS Asset Management, a
UK-based investor with e90 billion under management. The Investors’ Statement is intended
to demonstrate to extractive companies and host governments that the capital markets
unambiguously support the EITI principles.
VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008 jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj PAGE 413
Discussion
This case exhibits an interesting set of mechanisms in partnered governance: rule-making
through mobilization of NGOs and public pressure in host countries which then extends into
national politics. The EITI involved a not uncontroversial intrusion into the national politics of
developing countries by activist European governments (led by the UK and also including
Norway) where the stimulation of democratizing processes in developing countries put host
governments under dual pressure.
Ingeniously, persuasion was used in combination with economic sanctions by the World
Bank and other international organizations. The NGO partnership was also critical to
success by establishing the agenda and ensuring world attention. The ‘‘Publish what you
pay’’ movement was instrumental in triggering self-regulation and recruiting inside agency
within the host countries for support and local rule-making. The EITI was also ingenious in
staging implementation through stakeholder conferences. Here rules were disseminated
with increasing precision: from EITI principles to EITI criteria. However, a hard set of
sanctioning mechanisms is not yet in place and there are still varying interpretations on how
to proceed. Thus the EITI would seem to be caught between the desire to expand the
number of signatories and the potential hardship entailed for such signatories in terms of
hard implementation.
Partnered governance in the retailing industry, the ethical trading initiative:
implementing public policy through industrial value chains
The retailing industry, including such branches as food supply and clothing, is increasingly
being challenged to assume responsibility for working conditions, human rights and safety
in their value chain, which often stretches back to developing countries. Targeting the end
consumer, these companies are highly dependent on branding, and with reputation being
such a critical issue, negative press releases on practices in their supply chains can have
quite a detrimental effect.
A case in point is Nike, the footwear retailer and manufacturer, which has received intense
media criticism for bad working conditions in their factories in Asia. A similar criticism has
been leveled at the food chain ICA Norge, which has been forced to carry out internal
investigations after the press accused ICA of using child labor.
The Ethical Trading Initiative, ETI, aims to deal with these challenges in the retailing industry.
The critical areas targeted are monitoring and verification in order to create transparency
and disclosure of labor management. With its central focus on international labor law and
standards, including the ILO conventions, the ETI is also linked to public policy and can be
seen as partnered governance with respect to implementing public policy in an international
arena (EITI, 2006).
Evolution of the regulatory initiative
The ETI, launched in the UK in 1998, included NGOs and trade union and corporate
members working together to identify what constitutes ‘‘good practice’’ in code
implementation, and then promoting and sharing this good practice. The ETI identifies
good practice mainly through its members’ experimental projects and research, and shares
this through publications, seminars and conferences and the ETI website
(www.ethicaltrade.org). The ETI requires all corporate members to submit annual
progress reports on their code implementation activities, and has also developed
procedures for disengaging poor performers.
The Ethical Trading Initiative operates in close interface with more formal governmental
rule-making including the United Nations Universal Declaration of Human Rights; the
International Labour Organisation’s Tripartite Declaration of Principles concerning
Multinational Enterprises and Social Policy; Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises
developed by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD);
and the United Nations’ Convention on the Rights of the Child. The ETI Base Code and the
accompanying Principles of Implementation, although both negotiated and agreed by the
PAGE 414jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008
founding trade union, NGO and corporate members of ETI, therefore also reflect the most
relevant international standards with respect to labor practices and ILO conventions. Large
firms involved in retailing often flag extensive CSR policies and the strong engagement of
their value chains in ethical management.
Discussion
To sum up, the ethical trading initiative within the retailing industry highlights the challenge of
complex value chain issues in an industry that is highly dependent on branding. The
governance challenge is to create common labor practices in a system that often extends
over several continents and across a large variety of governance and industrial styles.
Implementation takes place largely through the sanctioning power of retailing industry with
access to tapping the buying power of dominant OECD markets. The combination of
reputation effects and brand building gives the global industrial system incentives to deliver.
Through the larger retailer’s direct multinational managerial systems and contractual
relations they already have the essential infrastructure in place to deliver credible results
beyond the reach of territorially-bound national legislatures. The Ethical Trading Initiative
serves to focus and strengthen these managerial and contractual practices so as to
implement international conventions on labor standards and human rights more efficiently.
In a partnered governance mode, the ETI may therefore also be seen as a supplementary
implementation tool for public policy in a typical ‘‘soft law’’ domain. The reference to
intergovernmentally endorsed standards serves to legitimize the ETI at the same time as the
deployment of industrial managerial and contractual resources and competencies obviously
strengthens the implementation of public policy. The large government contribution towards
funding the ETI is also an indication of the partnering mode of this initiative.
Partnered governance, concluding reflection
Both the conceptual analysis and the case examples indicate that there may be a strong
public policy argument for partnered governance when facing the challenge of integrating
social and environmental responsibilities into the globalizing economy. Elements of
partnered interplay between industry, government and civil society initiatives can be seen in
all our case examples.
The Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative exhibits an interesting set of mechanisms in
partnered governance: rule-making through mobilization of NGOs and public pressure in
host-countries, extending into national politics. Persuasion was used in combination with
economic sanctioning by the World Bank and other international organizations. The EITI also
made intelligent use of staged implementation through stakeholder conferences where rules
were disseminated with increasing precision: from EITI principles to EITI criteria.
In the Ethical Trading Initiative we have seen how implementation takes place largely through
the sanctioning power of the retailing industry with access to tapping the buying power of
dominant OECD markets. The direct multinational managerial systems and contractual
relations of larger retailers provide the essential infrastructure to deliver credible results
beyond the reach of traditional territorially-bound legislatures. In a partnered governance
mode, the ETI may therefore also be seen as a supplementary implementation tool for public
policy in a typical ‘‘soft law’’ domain. The reference to inter-governmentally endorsed
standards simultaneously served to legitimize the ETI and to strengthen the implementation
of public policy through the deployment of industrial, managerial and contractual resources
and competencies.
In the forest and paper and pulp industry, regulatory competition seems to have produced
higher-level regulation or higher levels of environmental and social quality in the industry
than under conventional authoritative regulation in the current global economy. Although the
government partnered industrial certification is less ambitious than the NGO-led FSC, the
engagement of industrial actors and government agencies has provided forest certification
on a far greater scale than would otherwise be possible.
VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008 jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj PAGE 415
We have argued for and found that media-driven ‘‘moral rights’’ bestowed on civil society
organizations establishes a basis for CSR-driven collective action beyond the formal
authority of nation states. Our findings here resonate with recent political science literature
highlighting that civil society organizations have managed to implant elements of public
accountability into the private transactional spaces of transnational firms (Ruggie, 2004) and
that this process has evolved relatively decoupled from the sphere of states. Ruggie points
to Wapner’s (1995) notion of World civic politics and Cutler’s (2002) concept of private
governance as building blocks of what he calls the new global public domain.
Our argument for partnered governance is based on the notion that public authorities at
different levels may achieve improved outreach by interfacing constructively with civic
politics. Civil politics engagements based on moral rather than formal rights may,
nevertheless, trigger processes that eventually result in formal governance arrangements.
Yet in many cases, formal governance may not even be desirable. In line with Luhmann
(1990), the complexity of global society may dictate more loosely coupled partnered
governance over formal government. Given the cultural diversity of the emerging global
society it is highly unlikely that politically mandated hierarchic governance can reach all the
way. Partnered governance, on the other hand, may allow advanced states and pioneering
companies to work together to raise the social and environmental bar above the global
lowest common denominator.
As long as the veto-players in global policy-making do not control global media, their
capacity to block policy processes to maintain minimalist social and environmental
standards may be overruled by moral persuasion in the public media. The direct or indirect
vulnerability, of industrial brand image to moral attacks may imply economic costs to
industrial actors and regimes that follow unacceptable practices.
In this way, ‘‘moral rights’’ based challenges by civil society organizations in the media
provides a healthy challenge both to autocratic planning and solely profit-centered
commercialization. Partnered governance strengthens this challenge and allows socially
and environmentally advanced states and regions to engage with civic society and
challenges to laggards on new arenas.
References
Ayres, I. and Braithwaite, J. (1995), Responsive Regulation: Transcending the Deregulation Debate,
Oxford Socio-Legal Studies,
Oxford.
Baylis, J. and Smith, S. (2005), The Globalization of World Politics: An Introduction to International
Relations, 3rd ed., Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Burns, T.R. and Flam, H. (1987), The Shaping of Social Organization: Social Rule System Theory with
Applications, Sage,
London.
Coase, R.H. (1960), ‘‘The problem of social cost’’, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 3, pp. 15-25.
Cutler, A.C. (2002), ‘‘Private international regimes and interfirm cooperation’’, in Bruce, R.H. and
Biersteker, T.J. (Eds), The Emergence of Private Authority in Global Governance, Cambridge University
Press, New York, NY, pp. 23-43.
Elkington, J. (2001), The Chrysalis Economy: How Citizen CEOs and Corporations Can Fuse Values and
Value Creation, Capstone, Oxford.
Extractive Industries’ Transparency Initiative (EITI) (2006), available at: www.eitransparency.org/section/
abouteiti/keydocuments
Financial Times (2005), ‘‘Extractive industries graft plans updated’’, Financial Times, 18 March.
Fombrun, C.J. (1996), Reputation: Realizing Value from the Corporate Image, Harvard Business School
Press, Boston, MA.
Forest Stewardship Council (FSC) (2006), available at: www.fsc.org/en
PAGE 416jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008
Fox, T., Ward, H. and Howard, B. (2002), Public Sector Roles in Strengthening Corporate Social
Responsibility: A Baseline Study, International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED),
London.
Freeman, R.E. (1984), Stakeholder Management: Framework and Philosophy, Pitman, Mansfield, MA.
Hart, S.L. (1997), ‘‘Beyond greening strategies for a sustainable world’’, Harvard Business Review,
January-February.
Kahn, A.E. (1988), The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Luhmann, N. (1990), Essays on Self-reference, Columbia University Press, New York, NY.
Martinelli, A. (2007), ‘‘Democratic global governance and sustainable development’’, working paper,
University of Milan, Milan.
Midttun, A. (1998), ‘‘The weakness of strong governance and the strength of soft regulation:
environmental governance in post-modern form’’, Innovation, Vol. 12 No. 2, pp. 235-50.
Midtun, A. and Gautesen, K. (2005), ‘‘Policy making and the role of government: realigning business
government and civil society’’, Journal of Corporate Governance, Vol. 5 No. 3, pp. 159-74.
Midttun, A., Gautesen, K. and Gjølberg, M. (2006), ‘‘The political economy of CSR in Western Europe’’,
Journal of Corporate Governance, Vol. 6 No. 4, pp. 369-85.
Porter, M.E. and Kramer, M.R. (2002), ‘‘The competitive advantage of corporate philantrophy’’, Harvard
Business Review, December, pp. 57-68.
Porter, M.E. and Kramer, M.R. (2006), ‘‘Strategy and society: the link between competitive advantage
and corporate social responsibility’’, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 84 No. 12, pp. 78-92.
Rousseau, J.J. (1988), On the Social Contract, Hackett, Indianapolis, IN.
Ruggie, J.G. (2004), ‘‘Reconstructing the global public domain – issues, actors and practices’’,
European Journal of international Relations, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 499-531.
Schmitter, P.C. and Streeck, W. (Eds) (1985), Private Interest Government: Beyond Market and State,
Sage, London.
State Oil Fund (2004), available at: www.un-az.org/undp/bulnews20/newsxcf2434.html (26 November).
Vig, N.J. and Axelrod, R.S. (1999), The Global Environment, CQ Press, Washington, DC.
Wapner, P. (1995), ‘‘Politics beyond the state: environmental activism and world civic politics’’, World
Politics, Vol. 47 No. 3, pp. 311-41.
Further reading
Abitibi (2005), ‘‘Annual report’’, available at: www.abitibiconsolidated.com/ACIWebSiteV3.nsf/Site/en/
investor/annual-reports.html
Anthony, O. (2001), Regulation, Economics and the Law, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
Baldwin, R., Scott, C. and Hood, C. (Eds.) (1998), A Reader on Regulation, Oxford University Press,
Oxford.
British Petroleum (2003), ‘‘Sustainability report’’, available at: www.bp.com/liveassets/bp_internet/
globalbp/STAGING/global_assets/downloads/C/cs_International_Promoting_greater_transparency_
from_businesses_2003
Chiquita (2005), ‘‘Corporate responsibility report’’, available at: www.chiquita.com
Deloitte Touche (2004), ‘‘The committee on the extractive industries transparency initiative of the
Republic of Azerbaijan’’, independent accountants’ report for the six months ending 30 June 2004.
Exxon Mobile (2005), available at: www.exxonmobil.com/corporate/Citizenship/Corp_citizenship_
Com_transparency.asp
GAP Inc. (2003), ‘‘Social responsibility report’’, available at: www.gapinc.com/social_resp/social_resp.
htm
Gulbrandsen, L.H. (2005), ‘‘Sustainable forestry in Sweden: the effect of competition among private
certification schemes’’, The Journal of Environment and Development, Vol. 14 No. 3, pp. 338-55.
VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008 jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj PAGE 417
Gunningham, N., Grabosky, P. and Sinclair, D. (1998), Smart Regulation: Designing Environmental
Policy, Clarendon Press, Oxford.
Habermas, J. (1981), Theorie des kommunikativen Handelns, (The Theory of Communicative Action),
Springer Verlag, Frankfurt.
Marks & Spencer (2005), ‘‘Ethical trading’’, available at: www.marksandspencer.com/thecompany/
ourcommitmenttosociety/suppliers/supplier_ethical.shtml
Nike (2004), ‘‘CSR report’’, available at: www.nike.com/nikebiz/gc/r/fy04/docs/FY04_Nike_CSR_
report_full
Norske Skog (2004), ‘‘Environmental report’’, available at: www.norskeskog.com/FullStory.
aspx?m ¼ 123
Rupert, O. (2006), ‘‘Price premiums for verified legal and sustainable timber’’, A study for the UK Timber
Trade Federation (TTF) and Department for International Development (DFID).
Corresponding author
Atle Midttun can be contacted at: atle.midttun@bi.no
PAGE 418jCORPORATE GOVERNANCEj VOL. 8 NO. 4 2008
To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: reprints@emeraldinsight.com
Or visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.