hist102——Essay 1 – 500words

Essay 1 – Additional Readings

The Wizard of Oz: A Parable on Populism

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

The Fable of the Allegory The Wizard of OZ in Economics

Writing Assignment for Essay 1

After reading both articles describe the parody that L. Frank Baum supposedly meant the “Wonderful Wizard of OZ” to portray. Do you find the assertion of the allegory persuasive or is the connection between the “Wonderful Wizard of OZ” and the economic situation at the turn of the century itself a fable as the Hansen article asserts? 

Signs of Friction a Portrait of America at Century’s End from A Fierce Discontent

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

Compare and Contrast the lives of the wealthy “10” and the lives of those who made up the working and farming classes of America. How do the ideas of “individualism” and “mutualism” help to define the differences between the various classes? Were farm families more like the wealthy “10” of the urban working families?
Be very detailed and specific in your essay. Be sure to use the conventions and writing guidelines established for the course.

Length: 2-3 pages; please keep the essay to no more than 3 pages. Format: Doubled-spaced, typed, font in Times New Roman or Arial, size 12. 1-inch margins all around. Written work for this course is to be submitted only in either Microsoft Word ( ) or Rich Text Format (.rtf).

  • Why an essay? Students will have the opportunity to gain an understanding of historical inquiry and writing. Reading is a significant part of any historical project. Students selecting an essay topic are also encouraged to use an additional source or two to enhance the experience. Please do not cite the textbook and online reference sources Wikipedia and Britannica, Infoplease, Sparknotes, Answers.com, Ask.com, et cetera. Make use of the online readings posted on the Calendar, supplemental materials posted in the session folders, or journal articles, government documents, newspapers, magazines, and books available through Ivy Tech Library’s Discover! Links to an external site.or print sources at your local library.
  • The Wizard of Oz: Parable on Populism
  • by Henry M. Littlefield

    On the deserts of North Africa in 1941 two tough Australian brigades went into battle
    singing:

    Have you heard of the wonderful wizard,
    The wonderful Wizard of Oz,
    And he is a wonderful wizard,
    If ever a wizard there was.

    It was a song they had brought with them from Australia and would soon spread to
    England. Forever afterward it reminded Winston Churchill of those “buoyant days.”[1]
    Churchill’s nostalgia is only one symptom of the world-wide delight found in an
    American fairy tale about a little girl and her odyssey in the strange land of Oz. The song
    he reflects upon came from a classic 1939 Hollywood production of the story, which
    introduced millions of people not only to the land of Oz, but to a talented young lady
    named Judy Garland as well.

    Ever since its publication in 1900 Lyman Frank Baum’s The Wonderful Wizard of Oz has
    been immensely popular, providing the basis for a profitable musical comedy, three
    movies, and a number of plays. It is an indigenous creation, curiously warm and
    touching, although no one really knows why. For despite wholehearted acceptance by
    generations of readers, Baum’s tale has been accorded neither critical acclaim, nor
    extended critical examination. Interested scholars, such as Russel B. Nye and Martin
    Gardiner, look upon The Wizard of Oz as the first in a long and delightful series of Oz
    stories, and understandably base their appreciation of Baum’s talent on the totality of his
    works[2].

    The Wizard of Oz is an entity unto itself, however, and was not originally written with a
    sequel in mind. Baum informed his readers in 1904 that he has produced The Marvelous
    Land of Oz reluctantly and only in answer to well over a thousand letters demanding that
    he creation another Oz tale. [3] His original effort remains unique and to some degree
    separate from the books which follow. But its uniqueness does not rest alone on its
    peculiar and transcendent popularity.

    Professor Nye finds a “strain of moralism” in the Oz books, as well as “a well-developed
    sense of satire,” and Baum stories often include searching parodies on the contradiction
    in human nature. The second book in the series, The Marvelous Land of Oz, is a blatant
    satire on feminism and the suffragette movement. [4] In it Baum attempted to duplicate
    the format used so successfully in The Wizard, yet no one has noted a similar play on
    contemporary movements in the latter work. Nevertheless, one does exist, and it reflects
    to an astonishing degree the world of political reality which surrounded Baum in 1900. In
    order to understand the relationship of The Wizard to turn-of-the-century America, it is
    necessary first to know something of Baum’s background.

    Born near Syracuse in 1856, Baum was brought up in a wealthy home and early became
    interested in the theater. He wrote some plays which enjoyed brief success and then, with
    his wife and two sons, journeyed to Aberdeen, South Dakota, in 1887. Aberdeen was a
    little prairie town and there Baum edited the local weekly until it failed in 1891. [5]

    For many years Western farmers had been in a state of loud, though unsuccessful, revolt.
    While Baum was living in South Dakota not only was the frontier a thing of the past, but
    the Romantic view of benign nature had disappeared we well. The stark reality of the dry,
    open plains and the acceptance of man’s Darwinian subservience to his environment
    served to crush Romantic idealism. [6]

    Hamlin Garland’s visit to Iowa and South Dakota coincided with Baum’s arrival. Henry
    Nash Smith observes,

    “Garland’s success as a portrayer of hardship and suffering on Northwestern farms was
    due in part to the fact that his personal experience happened to parallel the shock which
    the entire West received in the later 1880’s from the combined effects of low prices, …
    grasshoppers, drought, the terrible blizzards of the winter of 1886-1887, and the juggling
    of freight rates…”[7]

    As we shall see, Baum’s prairie experience was no less deeply etched, although he did not
    employ naturalism to express it.

    Baum’s stay in South Dakota also covered the period of the formation of the Populist
    party, which Professor Nye likens to a fanatic “crusade”. Western farmers had for a long
    time sought governmental aid in the form of economic panaceas, but to no avail. The
    Populist movement symbolized a desperate attempt to use the power of the ballot. [8] In
    1891 Baum moved to Chicago where he was surrounded by those dynamic elements of
    reform which made the city so notable during the 1890’s. [9]

    In Chicago Baum certainly saw the results of the frightful depression which had closed
    down up on the nation in 1893. Moreover, he took part in the pivotal election of 1896,
    marching in “torch-light parades for William Jennings Bryan”. Martin Gardiner notes
    besides, that he “consistently voted as a democrat…and his sympathies seem always to
    have been on the side of the laboring classes.” No one who marched in even a few such
    parades could have been unaffected by Bryan’s campaign. Putting all the farmers’ hopes
    in a basket labeled “free coinage of silver,” Bryan’s platform rested mainly on the issue of
    adding silver to the nation’s gold standard. Though he lost, he did at least bring the plight
    of the little man into national focus. [11]

    Between 1896 and 1900, while Baum worked and wrote in Chicago, the great depression
    faded away and the war with Spain thrust the United States into world prominence. Bryan
    maintained Midwestern control over the Democratic Party, and often spoke out against
    American policies toward Cuba and the Philippines. By 1900 it was evident that Bryan
    would run again, although now imperialism and not silver seemed the issue of primary
    concern. In order to promote greater enthusiasm, however, Bryan felt compelled once

    more to sound the silver leitmotif in his campaign. [12] Bryan’s second futile attempt at
    the presidency culminated in November 1900. The previous winter Baum had attempted
    unsuccessfully to sell a rather original volume of children’s fantasy, but that April,
    George M. Hill, a small Chicago publisher, finally agreed to print The Wonderful Wizard
    of Oz.

    Baum’s allegiance to the cause of Democratic Populism must be balanced against the fact
    that he was not a political activist. Martin Gardiner finds all through all of his writings “a
    theme of tolerance, with many episodes that poke fun at narrow nationalism and
    ethnocentrism.” Nevertheless, Professor Nye quotes Baum as having a desire to write
    stories that would “bear the stamp of our times and depict the progressive fairies of
    today.”[13]

    The Wizard of Oz has neither the mature religious appeal of a Pilgrim’s Progress, nor the
    philosophic depth of a Candide. Baum’s most thoughtful devotees see in it only a warm,
    cleverly written fairy tale. Yet the original Oz book conceals an unsuspected depth, and it
    is the purpose of this study to demonstrate that Baum’s immortal American fantasy
    encompasses more than heretofore believed. For Baum created a children’s story with a
    symbolic allegory implicit within its story line and characterizations. The allegory always
    remains in a minor key, subordinated to the major theme and readily abandoned
    whenever it threatens to distort the appeal of the fantasy. But through it, in the form of a
    subtle parable, Baum delineated a Midwesterner’s vibrant and ironic portrait of this
    country as it entered the twentieth century.

    We are introduced to both Dorothy and Kansas at the same time:

    “Dorothy lived in the midst of the great Kansas prairies, with Uncle Henry, who was a
    farmer, and Aunt Em, who was the farmer’s wife. Their house was small, for the lumber
    to build it had to be carried by wagon many miles. There was four walls, a floor and a
    roof, which made one room; and this room contained a rusty-looking cooking stove, a
    cupboard for the dishes, a table, three or four chairs, and the beds.

    When Dorothy stood in the doorway and looked around, she could see nothing but the
    great gray prairie on every side. Not a tree nor a house broke the broad sweep of flat
    country that reached to the edge of the sky in all directions. The sun had baked the
    plowed land into a gray mass, with little cracks running through it. Even the grass was
    not green, for the sun had burned the tops of the long blades until they were the same
    gray color to be seen everywhere. Once the house had been painted, but the sun blistered
    the paint and the rains washed it away, and now the house was as dull and gray as
    everything else.

    When Aunt Em came there to live she was a young pretty wife. The sun and wind had
    changed her too. They had taken the sparkle from her eyes and left them a sober gray;
    they had taken the red from her cheeks and lips, and they were gray also. She was thin
    and gaunt, and never smiled now. When Dorothy, who was an orphan, first came to her,
    Aunt Em had been so startled by the child’s laughter that she would scream and press her

    hand upon her heart whenever Dorothy’s merry voice reached her ears; and she still
    looked at the little girl with wonder that she could find anything to laugh at.

    Uncle Henry never laughed. He worked hard from morning till night and did not know
    what joy was. He was gray also, from his long beard to his rough boots, and he looked
    stern and solemn, and rarely spoke.

    It was Toto that made Dorothy laugh, and saved her from growing as gray as her other
    surroundings. Toto was not gray; he was a little black dog, with long silky hair and small
    black eyes that twinkled merrily on either side of his funny, wee nose. Toto played all
    day long, and Dorothy played with him, and loved him dearly.[14]

    Hector St. John de Crèvecoeur would not have recognized Uncle Henry’s farm; it us
    straight out of Hamlin Garland. [15] On it a deadly environment dominated everyone and
    everything except Dorothy and her pet. The setting is Old Testament and nature seems
    greyly impersonal and even angry. Yet it is a fearsome cyclone that lifts Dorothy and
    Toto in their house and deposits them “very gently — for a cyclone — in the midst of a
    country of marvelous beauty.” We immediately sense the contrast between Oz and
    Kansas. Here there are “stately trees bearing rich and luscious fruits… gorgeous flowers…
    and birds with … brilliant plumage” sing in the trees. In Oz “a small brook rushing and
    sparkling along” murmurs “in a voice very grateful to a little girl who had lived so long
    on the dry, gray prairie.”(p. 20)

    Trouble intrudes. Dorothy’s house has come down on the Wicked Witch of the East,
    killing her. Nature, by sheer accident, can provide benefits, for indirectly the cyclone has
    disposed of one of the two truly bad influences in the land of Oz. Notice that evil ruled in
    both the East and the West; after Dorothy’s coming it rules only in the West.

    The Wicked Witch of the East had kept the little Munchkin people “in bondage for many
    years, making them slave for her night and day.” (pp. 22-23) Just what this slavery
    entailed is not immediately clear, but Baum later gives us a specific example. The Tin
    Woodman, whom Dorothy meets on her way to the Emerald City, had been put under a
    spell by the Witch of the East. Once an independent and hard working human being, the
    Woodman found that each time he swung his axe it chopped off a different part of his
    body. Knowing no other trade he “worked harder than ever,” for luckily in Oz tinsmiths
    can repair such things. Soon the Woodman was all tin. (p. 59) In this way Eastern
    witchcraft dehumanized a simple laborer so that the faster and better he worked the more
    quickly he became a kind of machine. Here is a Populist view of evil Eastern influences
    on honest labor which could hardly be more pointed. [16]

    There is one thing seriously wrong with being made of tin; when it rains rust sets in. Tin
    Woodman had been standing in the same position for a year without moving before
    Dorothy came along and oiled his joints. The Tin Woodman’s situation has an obvious
    parallel in the condition of many Eastern workers after the depression of 1893.[17] While
    Tin Woodman is standing still, rusted solid, he deludes himself into thinking he is no
    longer capable of that most human of sentiments, love. Hate does not fill the void, a

    constant lesson in the Oz books, and Tin Woodman feels that only a heart will make him
    sensitive again. So he accompanies Dorothy to see if the Wizard will give him one.

    Oz itself is a magic oasis surrounded by impassable deserts, and the country is divided in
    a very orderly fashion. In the North and South the people are ruled by good witches, who
    are not quite as powerful as the wicked ones of the East and West. In the center of the
    land is the magnificent Emerald City ruled by the Wizard of Oz, a successful humbug
    whom even the witches mistakenly feel “is more powerful than all the rest of us
    together.” (p.24) Despite these forces, the mark of goodness, placed on Dorothy’s
    forehead by the Witch of the North, serves as protection for Dorothy throughout her
    travels. Goodness and innocence prevail even over the powers of evil and delusion in Oz.
    Perhaps it is this basic and beautiful optimism that makes Baum’s tale so
    characteristically American — and Midwestern.

    Dorothy is Baum’s Miss Everyman. She is one of us, levelheaded and human, and she has
    a real problem. Young readers can understand her quandary as readily as can adults. She
    is good, not precious, and she thinks quite naturally about others. For all the attractions of
    Oz, Dorothy desires only to return to the gray plains and Aunt Em and Uncle Henry. She
    is directed toward the Emerald City by the good Witch of the North, since the Wizard
    will surely be able to solve the problem of the impassable deserts. Dorothy sets out on the
    Yellow Brick Road wearing the Witch of the East’s magic Silver Shoes. Silver shoes
    walking on a golden road; henceforth Dorothy becomes the innocent agent of Baum’s
    ironic view of the Silver issue. Remember, neither Dorothy, nor the good Witch of the
    North, nor the Munchkins understand the power of these shoes. The allegory is
    abundantly clear. On the next to last page of the book Baum has Glinda, Witch of the
    South, tell Dorothy, “Your Silver Shoes will carry you over the desert…..If you had
    known their power you could have gone back to your Aunt Em the very first day you
    came to this country.” Glinda explains, “All you have to do is knock the heels together
    three times and command the shoes to carry you wherever you wish to go.” (p.257)
    William Jennings Bryan never outlined the advantages of the silver standard any more
    effectively.

    Not understanding the magic of the Silver Shoes, Dorothy walks the mundane — and
    dangerous — Yellow Brick Road. The first person she meets is a Scarecrow. After
    escaping from his wooden perch, the Scarecrow displays a terrible sense of inferiority
    and self-doubt, for he has determined that he needs real brains to replace the common
    straw in his head. William Allen White wrote an article in 1896 entitled “What’s the
    Matter with Kansas?” In it he accused Kansas farmers of ignorance, irrationality and
    general muddle-headedness. What’s wrong with Kansas are the people, said Mr. White.
    [18] Baum’s character seems to have read White’s angry characterization. But Baum
    never takes White seriously and so the Scarecrow soon emerges as innately a very shrewd
    and very capable individual.

    The Scarecrow and the Tin Woodman accompany Dorothy along the Yellow Brick Road,
    one seeking brains, the other a heart. They meet next the Cowardly Lion. As King of
    Beasts he explains, “I learned that if I roared very loudly every living thing was

    frightened and got out of my way.” Born a coward, he sobs, “Whenever there is danger
    my heart begins to beat fast.” “Perhaps you have heart disease,” suggests Tin Woodman,
    who always worries about hearts. But the Lion desires only courage and so he joins the
    party to ask help from the Wizard (pp.65-72).

    The Lion represents Bryan himself. In the election of 1896 Bryan lost the vote of Eastern
    Labor, though he tried hard to gain their support. In Baum’s story the Lion meeting the
    little group, “struck at the Tin Woodman with his sharp claws.” But, to his surprise, “he
    could make no impression on the tin, although the Woodman fell over in the road and lay
    still.” Baum here refers to the fact that in 1896 workers were often pressured into voting
    for McKinley and gold by their employers.[19] Amazed, the Lion says, “he nearly
    blunted my claws,” and he adds even more appropriately, “When they scratched against
    the tin it made a cold shiver run down my back” (pp. 67-68). The King of Beasts is not
    after all very cowardly, and Bryan, although a pacifist and an anti-imperialist in a time of
    national expansion, is not either. [20] The magic Silver Shoes belong to Dorothy,
    however. Silver’s potent charm, which had come to mean so much to so many in the
    Midwest, could not be entrusted to a political symbol. Baum delivers Dorothy from the
    world of adventure and fantasy to the real world of heartbreak and dissolution through the
    power of Silver. It represents a real force in a land of illusion, and neither the Cowardly
    Lion nor Bryan truly needs or understands its use.

    All together now the small party moves toward the Emerald City. Coxey’s Army of
    tramps and indigents, marching to ask President Cleveland for work in 1894, appears no
    more naively innocent than this group of four characters going to see a humbug Wizard,
    to request favors that only the little girl among them deserves.

    Those who enter the Emerald City must wear green glasses. Dorothy later discovers that
    the greenness of dresses and ribbons disappears on leaving, and everything becomes a
    bland white. Perhaps the magic of any city is thus self-imposed. But the Wizard dwells
    here and so the Emerald City represents the national Capitol. The Wizard, a little
    bumbling old man, hiding behind a facade of papier-mâché and noise, might be any
    president from Grant to McKinley. He comes straight from the fairgrounds on Omaha,
    Nebraska, and he symbolizes the American criterion for leadership — he is able to be
    everything to everybody.

    As each of our heroes enters the throne room to ask a favor the Wizard assumes different
    shapes, representing different views toward national leadership. To Dorothy he appears
    as an enormous head, “bigger than the head of the biggest giant.” An apt image for naive
    and innocent little citizen. To the Scarecrow he appears to be a lovely, gossamer fairy, a
    most appropriate form for an idealistic Kansas farmer. The Woodman sees a horrible
    beast, as would any exploited Eastern laborer after the trouble of the 1890’s. But the
    Cowardly Lion, like W. J. Bryan, sees a “Ball of Fire, so fierce and glowing he could
    scarcely bear to gaze upon it.” Baum then provides an additional analogy, for when the
    Lion “tried to go nearer he singed his whiskers and he crept back tremblingly to a spot
    nearer the door.” (p. 134)

    The Wizard has asked them all to kill the Witch of the West. The golden road does not go
    in that direction and so they must follow the sun, as have many pioneers in the past. The
    land they now pass through is “rougher and hillier, for there were no farms nor houses in
    the country of the West and the ground was untilled.” (p.140) The Witch of the West uses
    natural forces to achieve her ends; she is Baum’s version of sentient and malign nature.

    Finding Dorothy and her friends in the West, the Witch sends forty wolves against them,
    then forty vicious crows and finally a great swarm of black bees. But it is through the
    power of a magic golden cap that she summons the flying monkeys. They capture the
    little girl and dispose of her companions. Baum makes these Winged Monkeys into an Oz
    substitute for the plains Indians. Their leader says, “Once we were a free people, living
    happily in the great forest, flying from tree to tree, eating nuts and fruit, and doing just as
    we pleased without calling anybody master.” “This,” he explains, “was many years ago,
    long before Oz came out of the clouds to rule over this land” (p. 172). But like many
    Indian tribes Baum’s monkeys are not inherently bad; their actions depend wholly upon
    the bidding of others. Under the control of an evil influence, they do evil. Under the
    control of goodness and innocence, as personified by Dorothy, the monkeys are helpful
    and kind, although unable to take her to Kansas. Says the Monkey King, “We belong to
    this country alone, and cannot leave it.” (p. 213) The same could be said with equal truth
    of the first Americans.

    Dorothy presents a special problem to the Witch. Seeing the mark on Dorothy’s forehead
    and the Silver Shoes on her feet, the Witch begins “to tremble with fear, for she knew
    what a powerful charm belonged to them.” Then “she happened to look into the child’s
    eyes and saw how simple the soul behind them was, and that the little girl did now know
    of the wonderful power the Silver shoes gave her.” (p. 150) Here Baum again uses the
    Silver allegory to state the blunt homily that while goodness affords a people ultimate
    protection against evil, ignorance of their capabilities allows evil to impose itself upon
    them. The Witch assumes that proportions of a kind of western Mark Hanna or Banker
    Boss, who, through natural malevolence, manipulates the people and holds them prisoner
    by cynically taking advantage of their innate innocence.

    Enslaved in the West “Dorothy went to work meekly, with her mind made up to work as
    hard as she could; for she was glad the Wicked Witch had decided not to kill her.” (p.
    150) Many Western farmers have held these same grim thoughts in less mystical terms. If
    the Witch of the West is a diabolical force of Darwinian or Spencerian nature, then
    another contravening force may be counted upon the dispose of her. Dorothy destroys the
    evil Witch by angrily dousing her with a bucket of water. Water, that precious
    commodity which the drought-ridden farmers on the Great Plains needed so badly, and
    which if correctly used could create an agricultural paradise, or at least dissolve a wicked
    witch. Plain water brings an end to malign nature in the West.

    When Dorothy and her companions return to the Emerald City they soon discover that the
    Wizard is really nothing more than “a little man, with a bald head and a wrinkled face.”
    Can this be the ruler of the land? Our friends looked at him in surprise and dismay.

    “I thought Oz was a great Head,” said Dorothy….”And I thought Oz was a terrible Beast,”
    said the Tin Woodman. “And I thought Oz was a Ball of Fire,” exclaimed the Lion. “No;
    you are all wrong,” said the little man meekly. “I have been making believe.”

    Dorothy asks if he is truly a great Wizard. He confides, “Not a bit of it, my Dear; I’m just
    a common man.” Scarecrow adds, “You’re more than that…you’re a humbug.” (p. 184)

    The Wizard’s deception is of long standing in Oz and even the Witches were taken in.
    How was it accomplished? “It was a great mistake my ever letting you into the Throne
    Room,” the Wizard complains. “Usually I will not see even my subjects, and so they
    believe I am something terrible.”(p. 185) What a wonderful lesson for youngsters of the
    decade when Benjamin Harrison, Grover Cleveland and William McKinley were hiding
    in the White House. Formerly the Wizard was a mimic, a ventriloquist and a circus
    balloonist. The latter trade involved going “up in a balloon on circus day, so as to draw a
    crowd of people together and get them to pay to see the circus.” (p. 186-187) Such skills
    are as admirable adapted to success in late-nineteenth-century politics as they are to the
    humbug wizardry of Baum’s story. A pointed comment on Midwestern political ideals is
    the fact that our little Wizard comes from Omaha, Nebraska, a center of Populist
    agitation. “Why, that isn’t very far from Kansas,” cries Dorothy. Nor, indeed, are any of
    the characters in the wonderful Land of Oz

    The Wizard, of course, can provide the objects of self-delusion desired by Tin Woodman,
    Scarecrow and Lion. But Dorothy’s hope of going home fades when the Wizard’s balloon
    leaves too soon. Understand this: Dorothy wishes to leave a green and fabulous land,
    from which all evil has disappeared, to go back to the gray desolation of the Kansas
    prairies. Dorothy is an orphan; Aunt Em and Uncle Henry are her only family. Reality is
    never far from Dorothy’s consciousness and in the most heartrending terms she explains
    her reasoning to the good Witch Glinda.

    Aunt Em will surely think something dreadful has happened to me, and that will make
    her put on mourning; and unless the crops are better this year than there were last I am
    sure Uncle Henry cannot afford it. (p. 254)

    The Silver Shoes furnish Dorothy with a magic means of travel. But when she arrives
    back in Kansas she finds, “The Silver Shoes had fallen off in her flight through the air,
    and were lost forever in the desert.” (p.259) Were the “her” to refer to America in 1900,
    Baum’s statement could hardly be contradicted.

    Current historiography tends to criticize the Populist movement for its “delusions, myths
    and foibles,” Professor C. Vann Woodward observed recently.[22] Yet The Wonderful
    Wizard of Oz has provided unknowing generations with a gentle and friendly Midwestern
    critique of the Populist rationale on these very same grounds. Led by naive innocence and
    protected by good will, the farmer, the laborer and the politician approach the mystic
    holder of national power to ask for personal fulfillment. Their desires, as well as the
    Wizard’s cleverness in answering them, are all self-delusion. Each of these characters
    carries within him the solution to his own problem, were he only to view himself

    objectively. The fearsome Wizard turns out to be nothing more than a common man,
    capable of shrewd but mundane answers to these self-induced needs. Like any good
    politician he gives the people what they want. Throughout the story Baum poses a central
    thought; the American desire for symbols of fulfillment is illusory. Real needs lie
    elsewhere.

    Thus the Wizard cannot help Dorothy, for of all the characters only she has a wish that is
    selfless, and only she has a direct connection to honest, hopeless human beings. Dorothy
    supplies real fulfillment when she returns to her aunt and uncle, using the Silver Shoes,
    and cures some of their misery and heartache. In this way Baum tells us that the Silver
    crusade at least brought back Dorothy’s lovely spirit to the disconsolate plains farmer.
    Her laughter, love and good will are no small addition to that gray land, although the
    magic of Silver has been lost forever as a result.

    Noteworthy too is Baum’s prophetic placement of leadership of Oz after Dorothy’s
    departure. The Scarecrow reigns over the Emerald City, the Tin Woodman rules in the
    West and the Lion protects smaller beast in “a grand old forest.” Thereby farm interests
    achieve national importance, industrialism moves West and Bryan commands only a
    forest full of lesser politicians.

    Baum’s Fantasy succeeds in bridging the gap between what children want and what they
    should have. It is an admirable example of the way in which an imaginative writer can
    teach goodness and morality without producing the almost inevitable side effect of
    nausea. Today’s children’s books are either saccharine and empty, or boring and pedantic.
    Baum’s first Oz tale — and those which succeed it — are immortal not so much because
    the “heart-aches and nightmares are left out” as that “the wonderment and joy” are
    retained (p. 1).

    Baum declares “The story of ‘the Wonderful Wizard of Oz’ was written solely to pleasure
    children of today” (p. 1). In 1963 there are very few children who have never heard of the
    Scarecrow, the Tin Woodman or the Cowardly Lion, and whether they know W. W.
    Denslow’s original illustrations of Dorothy, or Judy Garland’s whimsical characterization,
    is immaterial. The Wizard has become a genuine piece of America folklore because,
    knowing his audience, Baum never allowed the consistency of the allegory to take
    precedence over the theme of youthful entertainment. Yet once discovered, the author’s
    allegorical intent seems clear, and it gives depth and lasting interest even to children who
    only sense something else beneath the surface of the story. Consider the fun in picturing
    turn-of-the-century America, a difficult era at best, using these ready-made symbols
    provided by Baum. The relationship and analogies outlined above are admittedly
    theoretical, but they are far too consistent to be coincidental, and they furnish a teaching
    mechanism which is guaranteed to reach any level of student.

    The Wizard of Oz says so much about so many things that it is hard not to imagine a
    satisfied and mischievous gleam in Lyman Frank Baum’s eye as he had Dorothy say,

    “And oh, Aunt Em! I’m so glad to be at home again!”

    Footnotes 1. Winston S. Churchill, Their Finest Hour (Cambridge, 1949). pp. 615-16.
    2. Martin Gardiner and Russel B. Nye, The Wizard of Oz and Who He Was (East Lansing,
    Mich., 1957), pp. 7 ff, 14-16, 19. Professor Nye’s “Appreciation” and Martin Gardiner’s
    “The Royal Historian of Oz” totaling some fourth-five pages, present as definitive an
    analysis of Baum and his works as is available today.
    3. L Frank Bum, The Marvelous Land of Oz (Chicago, 1904), p 3 (Author’s Note).
    4. Gardiner and Nye, Wizard, pp. 5-7,23.
    5. Ibid., pp. 20-22.
    6. See Calton F. Culmsee, Malign Nature and the Frontier (Logan, Utah, 1959), VII, 5,
    11, 14. The classic work in the field of symbolism in Western literature is Henry Nash
    Smith, Virgin Lane (New York, 1961), pp. 225-26, 261, 284-90.
    7. Ibid., p. 287.
    8. Russel B. Nye, Midwestern Progressive Politics (East Lansing, Mich., 1959). pp. 63,
    56-58, 75, 105. See also John D. Hicks, The Populist Revolt (Minneapolish, 1931), pp.
    82, 93-95, 264-68.
    9. See Ray Ginger, Altgeld’s America (New York, 1958).
    10. GArdiner and Nye, Wizard, p. 29
    11. See Williams Jennings Bryan, The First Battle (Lincoln, Neb., 1897), pp. 612-29.
    Two recent studies are notable: Harold U. Faulkner, Politics, REform and Expansion
    (New York, 1959), pp. 187-211 and Nye, Politics, pp. 105-20.
    12. See Richard Hofstadter’s shattering essay on Bryan in The American Political
    Tradition (New York, 1960), pp 186-205. Nye, Politics, pp. 121-22; Faulkner Reform, pp.
    272-75.
    13.Gardiner and Nye, Wizard, pp. 1, 30.
    14. L. Frank Baum, The Wonderful Wizard of Oz, pp. 11-13. All quotations cited in the
    text are from the inexpensive but accurate Dover paperback edition (New York, 1960).
    15. Henry Nash Smith says of Garland’s works in the 1890’s, “It has at last become
    possible to deal with the Western farmer in literature as a human being instead of seeing
    him through a veil of literary convention, class prejudice or social theory.” Virgin Land,
    p. 290.
    16. Hicks declares that from the start “The Alliance and Populist platforms championed
    boldly the cause of labor….” Revolt p. 324. See also Bryan’s Labor Day speech, Battle,
    pp. 375-83.
    17. Faulkner, Reform, pp. 142-43.
    18. Richard Hofstadter (ed.), Great Issues in American History (New York, 1960), II,
    147-53.
    19. Bryan, Battle, pp 617-618, “During the campaign I ran across various evidences of
    coercion, direct and indirect.” See Hicks, Revolt, p. 325, who notes that “For some reason
    labor remained singularly unimpressed” by Bryan. Faulkner finds overt pressure as well,
    Reform, pp. 208-9.
    20. Faulkner, Reform, pp. 257-58.
    21. Professor Nye observes that during 1890 (while Baum was editing his Aberdeen
    weekly) the Nebraska Farmer’s Alliance “launched the wildest campaign in Nebraska
    history.” Politics, p. 64-65. Bryan was a Senator from Nebraska and it was in Omaha that

    the Populist party ratified its platform on July 4, 1892. Seen Henry Steele Comager (ed.),
    Documents of American History (New York, 1958). II, 143-46.
    22. C. Vann Woodward, “Our Past Isn’t What It Used To Be,” The New York Times Book
    Review (July 28, 1963), p. 1; Hofstadter, Tradition

      The Wizard of Oz: Parable on Populism

    254 JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC EDUCATION

    The Fable of the Allegory:
    The Wizard of Oz in Economics

    Bradley A. Hansen

    Abstract: L. Frank Baum’s The Wonderful Wizard of Oz has become popular as a
    teaching tool in economics. It has been argued that it was written as an allegory
    of Populist demands for a bimetallic monetary system in the late 19th century.
    The author argues that Baum was not sympathetic to Populist views and did not
    write the story as a monetary allegory.

    Key words: economic history, monetary economics, teaching economics, The
    Wonderful Wizard of Oz
    JEL codes: A2, N1

    One method of enhancing student learning in economics courses is to intro-
    duce economic concepts through literature (Watts and Smith 1989; Kish-
    Goodling 1998; Scahill 1998). A well-known example in economics has been the
    incorporation of L. Frank Baum’s The Wonderful Wizard of Oz into the teaching
    of monetary issues. The book is presented as an allegory about Populists’
    demands for monetary expansion in the late 19th century. The allegory provides
    an efficient means of introducing students to debates about monetary issues
    because the elements of the story are so familiar. Students may also be intrigued
    by the unfamiliar interpretation.

    Although using The Wonderful Wizard of Oz as a means to discuss monetary
    issues may have pedagogical merits, economists have gone too far by claiming

    Bradley A. Hansen is a professor of economics at Mary Washington College (e-mail:
    bhansen@mwc.edu). The author thanks Ben and Joanna Gregson for letting him read all the Oz
    books to them. He also thanks Mary Eschelbach Hansen for carefully reading several drafts of this
    article, and Hirschel Kasper and four anonymous referees for helpful comments. He also thanks
    Hugh Rockoff and Ranjit Dighe. Neither gentleman entirely agrees with him, but both provided
    numerous thoughtful comments and suggestions.

    In this section, the Journal of Economic Education publishes articles
    concerned with substantive issues, new ideas, and research findings in
    economics that may influence or can be incorporated into the teaching of
    economics.

    HIRSCHEL KASPER, Section Editor

    Content Articles in Economics

    Summer 2002 255

    that the book was actually intended to be a monetary allegory. The primary evi-
    dence in support of the allegorical interpretation is what appears to be an extra-
    ordinary number of similarities between characters and events in the book and
    the people and events of the 1896 presidential campaign. The most popular ver-
    sion of the allegorical interpretation suggests not only that Baum described the
    Populist movement but that he was sympathetic to it. Historical research on
    Baum undermines both these propositions (Hearn 1992, 2000; Parker 1994; Tys-
    tad-Koupal 1996). Baum’s writings, as well as his life history, provide consider-
    able evidence that he did not have Populist sympathies and did not intend the
    book to be anything more than a delightful story. Indeed, the true lesson of The
    Wonderful Wizard of Oz may be that economists have been too willing to accept
    as a truth an elegant story with little empirical support, much the way the char-
    acters in Oz accepted the Wizard’s impressive tricks as real magic.

    THE WONDERFUL WIZARD OF OZ AS A MONETARY ALLEGORY

    In 1964, Henry Littlefield, a high school history teacher, described what ap-
    peared to be numerous coincidences between The Wonderful Wizard of Oz and
    the Populist movement of the late 19th century. Once viewed through a Populist
    lens, the symbolism of the book appears incredibly obvious. The Scarecrow rep-
    resents farmers, the Tin Woodman represents industrial workers, and the Cow-
    ardly Lion represents William Jennings Bryan.1 Dorothy was told to follow a yel-
    low brick road—the gold standard. People in the Emerald City were forced to
    look at everything through green glasses—greenbacks. The silver shoes—
    coinage of silver—really had the power to take Dorothy home. Oz itself refers to
    the abbreviation for an ounce of gold.

    Many economists have followed Littlefield’s lead. In an article on the use of
    literature in teaching economics, Watts and Smith (1989, 298) suggested the use
    of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz as a tool for enlivening the study of bimetallism,
    which they observed, “is often considered one of the dullest episodes in money
    and banking or economic history courses.” In the Journal of Political Economy,
    Rockoff (1990, 739) also claimed that the book was “not only a child’s tale but
    also a sophisticated commentary on the political and economic debates of the
    Populist Era.” He extended the allegorical interpretation by examining the story
    in light of both monetary theory and history and found additional symbols in the
    book such as the seven passages and three flights of stairs that Dorothy passed
    through in the palace of Oz (a symbol of the Crime of ’73).2 Like Watts and
    Smith, Rockoff (1990, 740) suggested that one of the primary benefits of the alle-
    gorical interpretation was pedagogical.

    Although Rockoff was not the first author to write on the subject, he must be
    credited with extending the interpretation and bringing it to a wide audience of
    economists. Rockoff’s article quickly became popular among economic histori-
    ans. Friedman (1990, 1167) cited it approvingly in his 1990 article, “The Crime
    of 1873.” When Whaples and Betts (1995) put together a collection of the most
    popular articles in American economic history, their survey showed that many
    economic historians included Rockoff’s article in their course reading lists.

    256 JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC EDUCATION

    The interpretation suggested by Rockoff’s article is the most common form of
    the allegorical interpretation of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz. He suggested that
    Baum was a Populist, or at least a Populist sympathizer, and that he wrote the book
    as an allegory. But advocates of the allegorical interpretation do not speak with a
    single voice. They disagree about whether or not Baum was a Populist and whether
    or not he intentionally wrote the story as an allegory. Clanton (1998, 183), for
    example, argued that Baum was a conservative Republican who “apparently
    amused himself by writing a subtle yet ingenious anti-Populist, gold standard tract
    in the form of a highly suggestive and enormously successful children’s story.” Rit-
    ter (1997b, 173) argued that The Wonderful Wizard of Oz is “a cultural and politi-
    cal satire which was neither simply pro-Populist or pro-capitalist.” She suggested
    that Baum’s intentions are not necessarily relevant. In her book Goldbugs and
    Greenbacks, Ritter (1997a, 21) argued that “motive is not at issue. The argument
    here is that Baum lived in the midst of a highly charged political environment and
    that he borrowed from the cultural materials at hand as he wrote.” Ranjit Dighe
    (forthcoming) argued that Baum was probably a progressive Republican, and
    although he may not have written The Wonderful Wizard of Oz as a monetary alle-
    gory, he was probably influenced by the political currents of the time. He also
    emphasized that the merits of the allegorical interpretation are primarily pedagog-
    ical. The common thread is a belief that L. Frank Baum, intentionally or uninten-
    tionally, portrayed political actors and events of the 1890s.

    The Rockoff interpretation has now spread from money and banking and eco-
    nomic history courses to economic principles courses. In his Principles of Eco-
    nomics, Mankiw (2001, 648) claimed that when Baum “sat down to write a story
    for children, he made the characters represent protagonists in the major political
    battle of his time. Although modern commentators differ somewhat in the inter-
    pretation they assign to each character there is no doubt that the story highlights
    the debate over monetary policy” (emphasis added).

    There is doubt. Evidence in support of the allegorical interpretation turns out
    to be rather meager. Rockoff (1990, 756) conceded that “Baum left no hard evi-
    dence that he intended his story to have an allegorical meaning: no diary entry,
    no letter, not even an offhand remark to a friend.” He claimed that the evidence
    in favor of the allegorical interpretation is that “It has been recognized indepen-
    dently by a number of thoughtful readers,” and that, “It is consistent with what
    we know of Baum’s politics” (Rockoff 1990, 756). Rockoff and others have
    claimed that Baum consistently voted Democrat and marched in torchlight
    parades for Bryan (Rockoff 1990; Baum and MacFall 1961; Gardner 1957). They
    also observed that Baum was the editor of a small-town newspaper in South
    Dakota before moving to Chicago in 1891 and suggested that this probably led
    to his Populist sympathies (Mankiw 2001; Ziaukas 1998).

    On closer examination, the evidence in favor of the allegorical interpretation
    melts away like the Wicked Witch of the West. In contrast, the evidence against
    the allegorical interpretation is abundant. It can be grouped into four categories.
    First, there have not been multiple independent discoveries of the allegorical
    interpretation. Second, Baum was not reluctant to express his political views, yet
    he did not express Populist sympathies and did express anti-Populist sympathies.

    Summer 2002 257

    Third, much of what is written in The Wonderful Wizard of Oz and Baum’s other
    children’s books is inconsistent with the allegorical interpretation. Fourth, much
    of what has been interpreted as political or economic symbolism in the book can
    be traced to other sources.

    THE CASE AGAINST THE ALLEGORICAL INTERPRETATION

    Independent Discovery

    Rockoff suggested the independent discovery by many individuals of the alle-
    gorical interpretation was evidence in its favor. Although it is true that many peo-
    ple have come to the conclusion that The Wonderful Wizard of Oz was an allego-
    ry of the Populist movement, no one appears to have come to the conclusion
    before Littlefield did, 64 years after the book was published. The New York Times
    review of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz, published September 8, 1900, when peo-
    ple should have been more aware of the supposed political symbolism in the text,
    treats it only as a fairy tale. Those who have made the argument in favor of an
    allegorical interpretation in recent years have almost all acknowledged Little-
    field’s lead (Rockoff 1990; Ritter 1997; Ziaukas 1998; Schweikart 2000; Watts
    and Smith 1989). Those who did not cite Littlefield cited others who did;
    Mankiw, for example, cited Rockoff. It is far from evident that many people have
    come to the conclusion independently.

    Political Sympathy

    The evidence on Baum’s politics is even more problematic than the evidence in
    favor of multiple independent discoveries of the allegory. Supporters of the allegor-
    ical interpretation point out that Baum marched in torchlight parades for Bryan and
    consistently voted for Democrats. This claim would appear to have great weight
    because of its appearance in a biography coauthored by Baum’s son, Frank Joslyn
    Baum. There are, however, reasons to be skeptical. To Please a Child: A Biography
    of L. Frank Baum was published in 1961, 40 years after the death of L. Frank Baum
    and 3 years after the death of Frank Joslyn Baum, at the age of 75. The claim that
    Baum consistently voted Democrat and marched for Bryan appears to have come
    from a biographical sketch of Baum by Gardner (1957, 29), published a few years
    before To Please a Child. Gardner provided no references for the claim. In addition,
    the story is at odds with the available evidence on Baum’s politics.3

    Baum’s support of woman suffrage, opposition to monopolies, and apparent
    sympathy for Asians and Native Americans have also been offered as evidence of
    Baum’s Populist-Democratic sympathies. Some of this evidence presents an
    accurate view of Baum, but a misleading and somewhat anachronistic view of
    late 19th century history. Baum’s support of woman suffrage and antitrust does
    not imply that he was a Democrat. His editing of a newspaper in South Dakota
    does not imply that he was a Populist. Some of these suggestions are simply
    incorrect: Baum consistently wrote editorials in support of Republican causes
    and candidates and was not particularly sympathetic to Native Americans.4

    It is true that Baum was an outspoken advocate of woman suffrage. His moth-

    258 JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC EDUCATION

    er-in-law, Matilda Joslyn Gage, was a participant at the Seneca Conference and
    co-author with Elizabeth Cady Stanton and Susan B. Anthony of History of
    Woman Suffrage. Matilda Gage often stayed with the Baums, and she encouraged
    L. Frank Baum to write down his children’s stories and to seek a wider audience
    for them. Baum clearly sided with his mother-in-law on the issue of suffrage. He
    promoted woman suffrage in his newspaper and actively campaigned for it in
    South Dakota (Tystad-Koupal 1996, 10–12). Baum also seems to have been in-
    terested in the problems associated with big business and monopoly. He worked
    for a time in 1901 on a musical entitled The Octopus, or The Title Trust. The mu-
    sical was never completed because Baum turned his attention to a musical ver-
    sion of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz. Baum also has an octopus in The Sea Fairies
    take offense at being compared to the Standard Oil Co. (Gardner 1957, 29).

    Many people now may associate women’s rights and the regulation of business
    more closely with the Democratic Party than the Republican Party. At the turn of
    the century neither support for antitrust nor support for woman suffrage was
    inconsistent with Republican party politics. For example, a Republican Congress
    passed the Sherman Antitrust Act, and a Republican President signed it into law.
    Theodore Roosevelt, the great trust buster, was also a Republican. Although Roo-
    sevelt did not take office until 1901, his views on big business were well known
    from his days as governor of New York (Bittlingmayer 1994, 381). Woman suf-
    frage also was not associated with just one political party. Initially, the woman
    suffrage movement had strong connections to the Republican Party because of its
    ties to the abolitionist movement. When Republicans supported voting rights for
    African Americans but not women, some leaders of the woman suffrage move-
    ment began to seek support without regard to party affiliation (Foner 1988, 252
    and 313). In the Midwest, one could find advocates of woman suffrage among
    both Populists and Republicans (Goldberg 1994).

    The Populist interpretation of Oz also associates Baum’s position as the editor
    of a midwestern paper with Populism. For example, Tim Ziaukas (1998, 8)
    explained that in 1887 Baum “moved to an area that would become the state of
    South Dakota, where he ran a variety store and worked in journalism and wit-
    nessed the desperation of the kinds of people who would be instrumental in the
    Populist movement.” However, the Plains States were far from being a solid block
    in support of Democratic-Populism. Although Independents (the original name
    used by the Populists in South Dakota) did well in the 1890 elections, their hold
    in South Dakota was not particularly strong. South Dakota was a clean sweep for
    the Republican Party in congressional elections in 1892 and 1894 (Hicks 1961,
    262 and 333) and went for the Republican presidential candidate Benjamin Har-
    rison in 1892. Bryan won South Dakota in the 1896 presidential contest, but
    McKinley outpolled him in much of the eastern border of the state, where Baum
    had lived. In 1900, South Dakota, like most of the other Plains States, returned to
    the Republicans and voted for McKinley (Faulkner 1959, 134, 207, and 277).

    Baum was one of the South Dakotans who never strayed from the Republican
    Party. Baum’s Aberdeen Saturday Pioneer was generally regarded as a Republi-
    can paper, and he himself referred to it as a Republican paper (Tystad-Koupal
    1996, 85). In his editorials, he consistently supported Republican candidates and

    Summer 2002 259

    Republican issues, such as the tariff.5 It is not necessary to decipher his views on
    Populists from his children’s books; he stated them quite clearly in his editorials.
    Although he was not as hostile toward Independents as the other Republican
    paper in Aberdeen, he could be very critical of particular Independents. After a
    speech by the Independent candidate for governor, he suggested the man had
    made “a fool of himself before all intelligent men” (Tystad-Koupal 1996, 90).

    Baum continued to support Republican causes after his move to Chicago in
    1891. In 1896 he published the following poem in the Chicago Herald Tribune:

    When McKinley gets the chair, boys,
    There’ll be a jollification
    Throughout our happy nation
    And contentment everywhere!
    Great will be our satisfaction
    When the “honest money” faction
    Seats McKinley in the chair!
    No more the ample crops of grain
    That in our granaries have lain
    Will seek a purchaser in vain
    Or be at mercy of the “bull” or “bear”;
    Our merchants won’t be trembling
    At the silverites’ dissembling
    When McKinley gets the chair!
    When McKinley gets the chair, boys,
    The magic word “protection”
    Will banish all dejection
    And free the workingman from every care;
    We will gain the world’s respect
    When it knows our coin’s “correct”
    And McKinley’s in the chair! (Hearn 1992)6

    He could hardly have been clearer in his opposition to Populist monetary pro-
    posals. Baum clearly believed that the combination of sound money and tariff
    protection, advocated by the Republican Party, would solve all the problems of
    merchants, farmers, and workingmen.

    Skeptical examination of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz, as well as subsequent Oz
    books (Baum wrote over a dozen more Oz books before his death in 1919), pre-
    sents even more problems for the allegorical interpretation of The Wonderful Wiz-
    ard of Oz. A particular problem is the issue of democracy. The Populist Party was
    not a single-issue party devoted solely to bimetallism. Populists were almost as
    concerned with democratic reform as with monetary reform. The Omaha Platform
    adopted in 1892 stated that “Corruption dominates the ballot box, the legislatures,
    the congress and touches even the ermine of the bench.” The party’s objective was
    to “restore the government of the Republic to the plain people.” Two of the 10 sup-
    plementary resolutions put forward by the platform committee directly addressed
    democratic institutions. Consider resolutions 7 and 8.

    7. RESOLVED, That we commend to the favorable consideration of the people and
    the reform press the legislative system known as the initiative and referendum.

    8. RESOLVED, That we favor a constitutional provision limiting the office of Pres-
    ident and Vice-President to one term, and providing for the election of Senators of
    the United States by a direct vote of the people (Hofstadter 1958, 152–53).7

    260 JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC EDUCATION

    Democratic reform was clearly central to Populist Party politics. The monetary
    problem was regarded as just one symptom of a broader problem. It would seem
    odd that someone writing a Populist allegory should completely disregard these
    other issues, especially someone as concerned with suffrage as Baum.

    Allegory: Alternate Interpretations

    In contrast to the Populists, the inhabitants of Oz were not democrats. Quite the
    contrary, they were avowed monarchists. All four of the main characters in The
    Wonderful Wizard of Oz were elevated to royalty. The Scarecrow became ruler of
    the Emerald City, the Tin Woodman became emperor of the Winkies, and of
    course, the Cowardly Lion became king of the forest. Upon her return to Oz in
    later books, Dorothy became a princess. Beginning with The Marvelous Land of
    Oz, the second book in the series, Oz is ruled by Ozma. The powers of Ozma were
    extensive. In The Emerald City of Oz, the sixth book in the series, Baum explained
    that, “All the property belonged to the Ruler. The people were her children and she
    cared for them” (Baum 1991, 30). People in Oz lived where the ruler told them to
    and worked at the jobs the ruler assigned them (Baum 1995, 185).

    Baum’s descriptions of the economy of Oz are also problematic for a Populist
    interpretation. Consider, for example, the dialogue between the shaggy man and
    the Tin Woodman about the Tin Woodman’s castle, from The Road to Oz (1991,
    the fifth book in the series):

    “It must have cost a lot of money,” remarked the shaggy man. “Money! Money in
    Oz!” cried the Tin Woodman. “What a queer idea! Did you suppose we are so vul-
    gar as to use money here?” “Why not?” asked the shaggy man. “If we used money
    to buy things with, instead of love and kindness and the desire to please one
    another, then we should be no better than the rest of the world,” declared the Tin
    Woodman. “Fortunately money is not known in the Land of Oz at all. We have no
    rich, and no poor; for what one wishes the others all try to give him, in order to
    make him happy, and no one in all Oz cares to have more than he can use.” (Baum
    1991, 164)

    Hardly the views of a sophisticated monetary theorist. It seems easier to apply a
    utopian interpretation to the Oz economy than a Populist one. It sounds more like
    a household economy, in which the relationship between ruler and ruled is the
    same as that between parent and child.8

    If Baum was not a Populist how can all the seeming coincidences be ex-
    plained? One might simply argue that a better understanding of Baum’s politics
    leads to a better understanding of the symbolism in The Wonderful Wizard of Oz.
    Clanton (1998, 183), for example, has argued that Baum was a Republican and
    that The Wonderful Wizard of Oz was written as a parody of Populists. Others
    have suggested that even if Baum was not a Populist and the book was not intend-
    ed as a full-scale allegory or parody, Baum’s writing was shaped by the political
    events of the time (Ritter 1997a, 21; Dighe forthcoming). Although one can try
    to reconcile a non-Populist Baum with an allegorical interpretation of Oz, many
    of the elements of the book that appear most laden with meaning actually have
    alternative explanations.

    Many of the elements of Baum’s stories can be traced to his experiences.

    Summer 2002 261

    Baum was born in Chittenango, New York, in 1856. His father rose from the
    ranks of the middle class to amass considerable wealth, then lost most of it. By
    1898, Baum had written and performed in plays; managed a chain of theaters;
    been a traveling salesman for axle grease, hardware, and china; edited a small
    paper and reported for a large one; managed a general store; written a book on
    raising chickens; and edited a magazine on window decorating. When he was liv-
    ing in Aberdeen, the area was experiencing a drought. Baum wrote a humorous
    column about a farmer who put green goggles on his horses so that they would
    think wood chips were grass, just like the Wizard made the inhabitants of Oz
    wear green glasses to convince them the city was made of emeralds (Baum and
    MacFall 1961, 74).9 One of Baum’s sons described the Tin Woodman as a prod-
    uct of Baum’s interest in window displays. According to Harry Baum, his father
    “wanted to create something eye catching, so he made a torso out of a washboil-
    er; bolted stovepipe arms and legs to it, and used the underside of a saucepan for
    the face. He topped it with a funnel hat, and what would become the inspiration
    for the tin woodman was born” (Carpenter and Shirley 1992, 43). Baum once
    explained that he had been fascinated with scarecrows since he was a child
    (Hearn 2000, 64). The story about pieces of china that come alive in chapter 20
    of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz hardly seems surprising from a man who had
    been a salesman for a china company.

    Much of the allegorical argument is built on the significance of colors: a City
    of Emeralds, a yellow brick road, silver shoes, and so forth. Although colors are
    important in The Wonderful Wizard of Oz, their significance arises from the col-
    laboration of Baum with the illustrator W. W. Denslow. Many people now read
    reprints of the Oz books that contain only black and white illustrations, but the
    original books were unique at the time for their use of color and the integration
    of text and illustrations (O’Reilly 1997, 42–47).10 Baum was the story teller, but
    he worked throughout the creative process with Denslow. Each part of Oz had its
    own dominant color. Blue was the color of the Munchkins, yellow was the color
    of the Winkies, and red the color of the Quadlings. The colors in the book
    changed as the characters moved through Oz. Such extensive use of color illus-
    trations was unusual and expensive, but Baum and Denslow were so committed
    to their vision that they agreed to pay for the printing plates themselves. Fur-
    thermore, whereas many of the colors appear significant in the allegorical inter-
    pretation, others are left unexplained. Why, for example, was the color of witch-
    es white? Why was Dorothy’s bonnet pink?

    Economist Rockoff adds a quantitative element to the case for the allegorical
    interpretation: the seven passages and three flights of steps (the Crime of ’73)
    that Dorothy passes through in the Wizard’s palace. Like the colors, however, this
    example selects one out of many numeric combinations to present as significant.
    What of the many other numerical combinations? The Emerald City had “nine
    thousand, six hundred and fifty-four buildings, in which lived fifty-seven thou-
    sand three hundred and eighteen people” (Baum 1991, 29). To go home, Dorothy
    clicked her heels three times and took three steps. The possessor of the Golden
    Cap was allowed to call the Flying Monkeys three times. What is the significance
    of these numbers?

    262 JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC EDUCATION

    Other Sources of Symbolism

    There is an alternative interpretation of Baum’s use of colors and numbers.
    The vivid colors and exact numbers, all expressed in simple language, are part of
    what Hollister refers to as the “three dimensionality” that made The Wonderful
    Wizard of Oz a success among children, if not among literary critics. He
    describes this quality as “the three dimensional experience of going into another
    universe where everything is brighter and more fragrant, more dangerous, and
    more alive” (Hollister 1983, 195). The importance of color is not restricted to
    Baum’s Oz books either. In Sky Island (1912), one of Baum’s attempts to escape
    from the Oz series, the story takes place on an island in the sky where pink peo-
    ple live on one-half and blue people on the other. It is difficult, if not impossible,
    to go more than a couple of pages in one of Baum’s books without a reference to
    a color or a number. These are descriptions that children understand and can
    readily imagine.

    Other historians have suggested additional sources for Oz. Leach (1993,
    246–60) argued that the book is largely a product of Baum’s interest in theoso-
    phy. Parker (1994) argued that Baum was strongly influenced by the Chicago
    World’s Fair of 1893. Baum was clearly a man with wide-ranging interests.
    Hearn’s The Annotated Wizard of Oz (2000) provides innumerable examples of
    contemporary events that are likely to have influenced Baum’s writing. He was
    aware of developments in politics, religion, and popular culture. It seems rea-
    sonable that many of these developments influenced his writing, but the available
    evidence strongly suggests that he did not write The Wonderful Wizard of Oz as
    a monetary allegory.

    CONCLUSION

    Rockoff noted that the empirical evidence that Baum wrote The Wonderful
    Wizard of Oz as an allegory was slim, but he compared an allegorical interpreta-
    tion to a model and suggested that “economists should not have any difficulty
    accepting, at least provisionally, an elegant but controversial model” (Rockoff
    1990, 757). He was right—we did not have any difficulty accepting it. Despite
    Rockoff’s warning, we appear to have accepted the story wholeheartedly rather
    than provisionally, simply because of its elegance.11

    It is as difficult to prove that The Wonderful Wizard of Oz was not a monetary
    allegory as it is to prove that it was. In the end, we will never know for certain what
    Baum was thinking when he wrote the book. I suggest that the vast majority of the
    evidence weighs heavily against the allegorical interpretation. It should be remem-
    bered that no record exists that Baum ever acknowledged any political meanings in
    the story and that no one even suggested such an interpretation until the 1960s.
    There certainly does not seem to be sufficient evidence to overwhelm Baum’s
    explicit statement in the introduction of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz that his sole
    purpose was to entertain children and not to impress upon them some moral.

    The Wonderful Wizard of Oz is a great story. Telling students that the Populist
    movement was like The Wonderful Wizard of Oz does seem to catch their atten-

    Summer 2002 263

    tion. It may be a useful pedagogical tool to illuminate the debate on bimetallism,
    but we should stop telling our students that it was written for that purpose.

    NOTES

    1. Bryan was the presidential candidate representing the fusion of the Democratic and Populist par-
    ties in 1896. He lost to the Republican William McKinley.

    2. The Crime of ’73 was used by proponents of bimetallism to refer to the Coinage Act of 1873,
    which omitted coinage of the silver dollar.

    3. Gardner almost certainly misinterpreted one aspect of Baum’s politics when he suggested that
    his writings betrayed a distaste for feminism and woman suffrage (Gardner 1957, 21).

    4. It has also been suggested that the Winged Monkeys represented Plains Indians and the Winkies
    represented Asians (either Filipinos or Chinese immigrants) and that Baum was “clearly sympa-
    thetic to the plight of the Philippines (and to the Plains Indians)” (Rockoff 1990, 751). Baum’s
    editorials in the Aberdeen Saturday Pioneer indicate that his sympathy was limited. He declared
    that whites had wronged the Native Americans but argued that the only solution to the Indian
    problem was total extermination of these “untamed and untamable creatures” (Tystad-Koupal
    1996, 147).

    5. It might be suggested that Baum was merely pandering to a Republican audience, but he also
    used his editorials to discuss issues that do not appear to have been popular in Aberdeen, such as
    advocating woman suffrage and challenging the teachings of local churches (Hearn 2000, xxiii).

    6. Chicago Sunday Times Herald, July 12, 1896. Reprinted in Hearn (1992).
    7. Prior to the 17th Amendment, adopted in 1913, senators were selected by state legislatures rather

    than by direct election.
    8. Thanks to Mary Hansen for pointing this out to me.
    9. Baum does not seem to have been very concerned with being consistent from one book to the

    next. By the time of The Emerald City of Oz, the city is actually emerald encrusted.
    10. The Books of Wonder reprints of the Oz series contain the original color illustrations by W. W.

    Denslow and John Neill. Particularly spectacular are the illustrations in The Emerald City of Oz,
    each of which incorporates a special metallic green ink. The annotated centennial edition edited
    by Michael Patrick Hearn also reproduces the original appearance of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz.

    11. I use the term “we” literally because I told the story to my classes for several years. I did not start
    to doubt it until I read the Oz series to Ben and Joanna Gregson.

    REFERENCES

    Baum, F. J., and R. MacFall. 1961. To please a child: A biography of L. Frank Baum. Chicago:
    Reilly and Lee.

    Baum, L. F. 1900. The wonderful wizard of Oz. Chicago: Hill.
    1904. The marvelous land of Oz. Chicago: Reilly and Britton.
    1912. Sky island. Chicago: Reilly and Britton.
    1991. [1909] The road to Oz. New York: William Morrow.
    1993. [1910] The Emerald City of Oz. New York: William Morrow.
    1995. [1913] The patchwork girl of Oz. New York: William Morrow.

    Bittlingmayer, G. 1996. Antitrust and business activity: The first quarter century. Business History
    Review 70 (3): 363–401.

    Carpenter, A. J., and J. Shirley. 1992. L. Frank Baum: Royal historian of Oz. Minneapolis: Lerner.
    Dighe, R. S. Forthcoming. The historian’s wizard of Oz: Reading L. Frank Baum’s classic as a polit-

    ical and monetary allegory. Westport, Conn.: Praeger.
    Faulkner, H. U. 1959. Politics, reform and expansion. New York: Harper & Row.
    Foner, E. 1988. Reconstruction: America’s unfinished revolution, 1863–1877. New York: Harper

    & Row.
    Friedman, M. 1990. The crime of 1873. Journal of Political Economy 98 (6): 1159–94.
    Gardner, M. 1957. The royal historian of Oz. In M. Gardner and R. Nye, eds., The wizard of Oz and

    who he was. East Lansing: Michigan State University Press.
    Goldberg, M. 1994. Non-partisan and all-partisan: Rethinking woman suffrage and party politics in

    gilded age Kansas. Western Historical Quarterly, 25 (1): 2–44.
    Hearn, M. P. 1992. Oz author never championed Populism. New York Times Jan. 10.
    ———. 2000. The annotated wizard of Oz: A centennial edition. New York: W. W. Norton.
    Hicks, J. 1961. The Populist revolt. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.

    264 JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC EDUCATION

    Hofstadter, R. 1958. Great issues in American history, vol. 2: 1864–1957. New York: Vintage.
    Hollister, C. W. 1983. Oz and the fifth criterion. In M. P. Hearn, ed., The wizard of Oz. New York:

    Schoken. Reprinted from 1971. The Baum Bugle (Christmas issue):5–8.
    Kish-Goodling, D. M. 1998. Using The Merchant of Venice in teaching monetary economics. Jour-

    nal of Economic Education 29 (Fall): 330–39.
    Leach, W. 1993. Land of desire: Merchants, power and the rise of a new American culture. New York:

    Pantheon.
    Littlefield, H. M. 1964. The Wizard of Oz: Parable on Populism. American Quarterly 16 (1): 47–58.
    Mankiw, N. G. 2001. Principles of economics. 2nd ed. Orlando: Dryden.
    Nye, R. 1957. An appreciation. In M. Gardner and R. Nye, eds., The wizard of Oz and who he was.

    East Lansing: Michigan State University Press.
    O’Reilly, M. 1997. Oz and beyond: The fantasy world of L. Frank Baum. Lawrence: University Press

    of Kansas.
    Parker, D. 1994. The rise and fall of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz as a “parable of populism.” Journal

    of the Georgia Association of Historians 15: 49–63.
    Ritter, G. 1997a. Goldbugs and greenbacks: The antimonopoly tradition and the politics of finance in

    America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
    ———. 1997b. Silver slippers and a golden cap: L. Frank Baum’s The Wonderful Wizard of Oz and

    historical meaning in American politics. Journal of American Studies 31 (2): 171–202.
    Rockoff, H. 1990. The wizard of Oz as a monetary allegory. Journal of Political Economy 98 (4):

    739–60. Reprinted in R. Whaples and D. C. Betts, eds., 1995. Historical perspectives on the Amer-
    ican economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Scahill, E. M. 1998. A Connecticut yankee in Estonia. Journal of Economic Education 29 (Fall):
    340–46.

    Schweikart, L. 2000. The entrepreneurial adventure: A history of business in the United States.
    Orlando, Fla.: Harcourt Brace.

    Tystad-Koupal, N., ed. 1996. Our landlady. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.
    Watts, M., and R. E. Smith. 1989. Economics in literature and drama. Journal of Economic Educa-

    tion 20 (Summer): 291–307.
    Whaples, R., and D. C. Betts, eds. 1995. Historical perspectives on the American economy. Cam-

    bridge: Cambridge University Press.
    Ziaukas, T. 1998. Baum’s wizard of Oz as gilded age public relations. Public Relations Quarterly 43

    (3): 7–11.

    A Fierce Discontent:
    The Rise and Fall of the Progressive Movement in America; 1870 – 1920.

    By Michael McGerr, Ph.D. Indiana University

  • Chapter One: Signs of Friction; Portrait of America at Century’s End
  • In one of Chicago’s elite clubs on election night in November 1896, a group of rich men were

    euphoric. After a tense, uncertain campaign, their presidential candidate, the Republican William
    McKinley, had clearly defeated the Democratic and Populist nominee, William Jennings Bryan. As
    the celebration continued past midnight, a wealthy merchant, recalling his younger days, began a
    game of Follow the Leader. The other tycoons joined in and the growing procession tromped across
    sofas and chairs and up onto tables. Snaking upstairs and down, the line finally broke up as the men
    danced joyfully in one another’s arms.

    Their euphoria was understandable. McKinley’s victory climaxed not only a difficult election but
    an intense, generation-long struggle for control of industrializing America. For Chicago’s elite, the
    triumph of McKinley, the sober former governor of Ohio, meant that the federal government was in
    reliable, Republican hands. The disturbing changes that Bryan had promised-the reform of the
    monetary system, the dismantling of the protective tariff-would not pass. The frightening prospect of
    a radical alliance of farmers and workers had collapsed. The emerging industrial order, the source of
    their wealth and power, seemed safe.2

    McKinley’s victory certainly was a critical moment, but the election did not settle the question of
    control as fully as those rich men in Chicago would have liked. The wealthy could play Follow the
    Leader, but it was not at all clear that the rest of the nation was ready to follow along. Driven by the
    industrial revolution, America had grown enormously in territory, population, and wealth in the
    nineteenth century. The United States was not one nation but several; it was a land divided by
    region, race, and ethnicity. And it was a land still deeply split by class conflict. The upper class
    remained a controversial group engineering a wrenching economic transformation, accumulating
    staggering fortunes, and pursuing notorious private lives. Just three months later another party, this
    one in New York City, highlighted the precariousness of upper-class authority at the close of the
    nineteenth century.

    While McKinley and Bryan battled for the presidency, Cornelia Bradley Martin had been plotting
    her own coup in the social wars of New York’s rich. She and her husband, Bradley, were no
    newcomers to the ranks of wealthy Manhattan. Cornelia’s father had been a millionaire merchant in
    New York; Bradley’s, a banker from a fine Albany family. Though wealthy, their parents had lived
    by the old Victorian virtues. Cornelia’s father, it was said, had been “domestic in his tastes”;
    Bradley’s father, who early practiced “absolute self-denial” “never lost an opportunity of instilling”
    in his sons “ideas of the importance of work and one’s duty towards others in every-day life.”
    Cornelia and Bradley, married in 1869, had moved away from the old values. One sign of the change
    was their surname, which somewhere along the line borrowed Bradley’s first name, occasionally
    added a hyphen, and doubled from “Martin” to “Bradley-Martin.” Another was Cornelia’s collection
    of jewelry, which included pieces from the French crown jewels, most notably a ruby necklace that
    had belonged to Marie Antoinette. Never “domestic” in their tastes, the Bradley-Martins had become
    well known in New York social circles, especially for their renowned parties in 1885 and 1890.3

    In the depression winter of 1897, Cornelia arranged a costume ball at the Waldorf Hotel that
    would, she hoped, eclipse not only her previous efforts but also Alva Vanderbilt’s famous ball of
    1883, widely recognized as the greatest party in the history of the city. Cornelia was not bashful
    about her intentions. For weeks before the ball, her secretary made sure that the papers got all the

    details. Yet the publicity was not quite what Cornelia had expected. Across the country, preachers
    and editorial writers argued over the propriety of a party that would cost hundreds of thousands of
    dollars amid the worst depression in the nation’s history. At the fashionable St. George’s Episcopal
    Church in New York, rector Dr. William Rainsford urged his congregation, which included financier
    J. P. Morgan, to forgo the ball. “Never were the lines between the two classes-those who have
    wealth and those who envy them-more distinctly drawn.” Rainsford warned. “Such elaborate and
    costly manifestations of wealth would only tend to stir up… widespread discontent” and “furnish
    additional texts for sermons by the socialistic agitators.” “Every thoughtful man” agreed a
    parishioner, “must have seen signs of friction between the upper ten and the lower. Whatever tends
    to increase it, as very elaborate social affairs may, can well be spared now” The pastor of Fifth
    Avenue Baptist Church, where John D. Rockefeller worshipped, preached that wealth should be used
    for philanthropy. Undeterred, Cornelia went ahead. Her supporters claimed that the expenditures for
    the ball would stimulate the economy.

    Some invited guests decided not to attend. But about six or seven hundred turned up, in costume,
    when the great night came on February 10. Bradley dressed as a member of the court of Louis XV.
    Cornelia, despite her Marie Antoinette necklace, dressed as another luckless queen, Mary Stuart.
    Like a queen, the hostess greeted her guests from a raised dais “beneath a canopy of rare tapestries.”
    There were mirrors, tables laden with food, “a wild riot of roses” and “mimic woodland bowers.”
    The scene “reproduced the splendor of Versailles in New York, and I doubt if even the Roi Soleil
    himself ever witnessed a more dazzling sight.” Bradley’s brother, Frederick Townsend Martin,
    remembered. ‘The power of wealth with its refinement and vulgarity was everywhere. It gleamed
    from countless jewels, and it was proclaimed by the thousands of orchids and roses, whose fragrance
    that night was like incense burnt on the altar of the Golden Calf’ Royalty was everywhere, too-”per-
    haps a dozen” Marie Antoinettes came to the ball. Amid all the bewigged and bejeweled royalty, a
    reporter noted, there were hardly any American costumes. Only one or two George Washingtons
    reminded the guests of their republican origins. Outside, about 250 police closed the sidewalks to
    pedestrians and braced for trouble. While his wife danced inside, Police Commissioner Theodore
    Roosevelt directed his men as they watched for anyone “likely to prove dangerous from an
    anarchistic viewpoint.”

    The revolutionary moment never came, but Cornelia’s triumph turned into disaster anyway.
    Across the country, elite opinion condemned the Bradley Martins. The Chicago Tribune gave its
    verdict by quoting Shakespeare’s
    Puck: “What fools these mortals be.” Worse, New York City itself suddenly became inhospitable.
    Municipal officials, noting Bradley’s opulence, raised his property taxes. The members of the city’s
    elite clubs pronounced the Bradley Martins’ ball “magnificent” but “stupid.” Unlike Marie
    Antoinette and Mary Stuart, Cornelia kept her head, but she and Bradley soon left the United States
    to begin a self-imposed exile. Selling their mansion in Manhattan, the Bradley Martins bought a new
    place in London, where their daughter had married Lord Craven a few years before. In 1899, they
    returned briefly to New York to give a defiant farewell dinner party at the Waldorf at the cost of $u6
    a plate. From then on, the Bradley Martins divided their time between London and Balmacaan,
    Bradley’s estate in Scotland. They left behind a bemused Frederick Townsend Martin. Years later he
    still could not understand why all this had happened. After all, the ball had helped the economy
    because “many New York shops sold out brocades and silks which had been lying in their stock-
    rooms for years” “I cannot conceive” Frederick wrote sadly, “why this entertainment should have
    been condemned.”

    If McKinley’s victory emphasized the strength of the “upper ten” the Bradley Martins’ ball

    epitomized their weakness. Absurd as it was, the affair highlighted the cultural isolation and internal
    division that plagued the wealthy. The industrial upper class upheld a set of values at odds with those
    of other classes. Approaching life so differently from the rest of America, the rich could not
    command respect from farmers and workers. Even among themselves, the “upper ten” disagreed
    how best to live their lives and secure their future. The party did not last very long at all.

    Cornelia Bradley Martin staged her costume ball when class differences were more pronounced

    than at any time in the history of industrial America. The end of the nineteenth century saw more
    than just “signs of friction between the upper ten and the lower;” wage workers, farmers, and the
    rich were alien to one another. That sense of strangeness was not only a matter of obvious
    differences in material circumstances. By choice and by necessity, America’s social classes lived
    starkly divergent daily lives and invoked different and often conflicting values to guide, explain, and
    justify their ways of life. The classes held distinctive views on fundamental issues of human
    existence: on the nature of the individual; on the relationship between the individual and society; on
    the roles of men, women, children, and the family; and on the relative importance of work and
    pleasure. What would become the Progressive Era, an extraordinary explosion of middle-class
    activism, began as an unprecedented crisis of alienation amid the extremes of wealth and poverty in
    America.

    In a land of some 76 million people, the “upper ten” were no more than a tiny minority, a mere
    sliver of the nation. Wealthy capitalists, manufacturers, merchants, landowners, executives,
    professionals, and their families made up not “ten” but only I or 2 percent of the population. These
    were the people who owned the majority of the nation’s resources and expected to make the majority
    of its key decisions. They could be found in cities, towns, and rural estates across the country. Their
    ranks included the nation’s roughly four thousand millionaires, fabulously rich by almost any
    standard. Their most visible and most powerful members were the two hundred or so families worth
    at least $20 million, fortunes with few parallels in history. Concentrated in the Northeast and
    especially New York State, theirs were the famous names of American capitalism-Vanderbilt,
    Whitney, Carnegie, Harriman, and Morgan. Probably the greatest fortune of them all – a billion
    dollars by 1913 – belonged to John D. Rockefeller, the leader of Standard Oil.

    Membership in the upper ten was never only a matter of precise calculation in dollars; it was also
    a matter of origins, experience, and outlook. Wealthy Americans shared several attributes that made
    them a homogenous and distinctive group, similar to one another and different from the rest of
    the population. In an increasingly diverse nation of new and old immigrants, the upper class came
    mostly from English stock, from families long in America. In a largely Protestant land, they
    belonged, by birth or conversion, to the smaller, most fashionable Protestant denominations-
    Episcopalian, Presbyterian, and Congregational. With only occasional exceptions, they came from
    middle- and upper-class origins. Hardly any matched Andrew Carnegie’s storied rise from rags to
    riches, from working-class bobbin boy in a textile factory to multimillionaire steel baron. While
    fewer than 10 percent of the population had even graduated from high school, many of the upper ten
    had gone to college or professional school.

    Above all, the upper ten shared a fundamental understanding about the nature of the individual.
    Glorifying the power of individual will, the wealthy held to an uncompromising belief in the
    necessity of individual freedom. To Andrew Carnegie, “Individualism” was the very “foundation” of
    the human race. “Only through exceptional individuals, the leaders, man has been able to ascend”
    Carnegie explained. “[It] is the leaders who do the new things that count, all these have been
    Individualistic to a degree beyond ordinary men and worked in perfect freedom; each and everyone a

    character unlike anybody else; an original, gifted beyond most others of his kind, hence his
    leadership.” It was just this strong-willed sense of her” exceptional” individuality that inspired
    Cornelia Bradley Martin’s idea for a ball; and it was just this sense of her right to “perfect freedom”
    that enabled her to stick to her plans in the face of so much condemnation.

    The upper ten attributed the hardships of the poor not to an unfair economic system but to
    individual shortcomings. The remedy was individual regeneration rather than government action.
    “[The] failures which a man makes in his life are due almost always to some defect in his
    personality, some weakness of body, or mind, or character, will, or temperament” wrote John D.
    Rockefeller. “The only way to overcome these failings is to build up his personality from within, so
    that he, by virtue of what is within him, may overcome the weakness which was the cause of the
    failure.” Individualism, moreover, helped the wealthy resolutely deny the existence of social classes,
    despite all the signs of friction around them. “The American Commonwealth is built upon the
    individual;” explained the renowned corporate lawyer and US. Senator Chauncey Depew of New
    York. “It recognizes neither classes nor masses.”

    Upper-class individualism was more than just a crude version of “might makes right.” These men
    and women had grown up in a land dedicated to individualism. In the Revolutionary era, the nation’s
    sacred documents-the Declaration of Independence, the Constitution, and the Bill of Rights
    proclaimed the dignity and worth of the individual. By the nineteenth century, that notion was so
    powerful and so distinctively American that the visiting French observer Alexis de Tocqueville
    coined the term individualism to describe it. The relentless spread of capitalism reaffirmed the
    individualist creed, but with a new emphasis on each person’s ownership of his or her labor. By mid-
    century, this reworked individualism drove the abolitionist assault on slavery and spurred the
    Northern war against the South. Individualism justified the emerging factory system, built on
    individual workers’ free exchange of their labor for wages. Individualism provided the core of the
    Victorian culture that taught middle-class men self-discipline and self-reliance in the struggle for
    success. “Take away the spirit of Individualism from the people” warned Wall Street veteran Henry
    Clews, “and you at once eliminate the American spirit – the love of freedom, – of free industry, – free
    and unfettered opportunity, – you take away freedom itself.”

    Ironically, the wealthy themselves challenged freedom and individualism by creating the nation’s
    pioneering big businesses, the giant trusts and corporations that employed the first white-collar
    “organization men” There were even a few “organization men” among the upper ten. William Ellis
    Corey, the second president of United States Steel, “is part of the mechanism itself;” wrote an
    observer early in the twentieth century. “He feels himself to be a fraction, rather than a unit. His
    corporation is an organism like a human body, and he is the coordinating function of its brain:”

    Yet, men like Corey were unusual. For one thing, many of the wealthy did not share his
    familiarity with corporate life. In the industrial city of Baltimore, sixth largest in the nation in 1900,
    only about one-fifth of leading businessmen had made their careers as bureaucrats. Of the 185
    leaders of the largest American firms between 1901 and 1910, just under half were career
    bureaucrats, men who had never had their own businesses. But even business leaders accustomed to
    bureaucracy tended to see themselves as individual units rather than fractions of some larger whole.
    Railroad executives, members of the nation’s pioneering corporate hierarchies, still rejoiced in
    “competitive individualism” after decades of collective enterprise. Such people may have felt a
    special tie to their organizations, but that did not prevent them from feeling superior to everybody
    else. William Ellis Corey was, after all, United States Steel’s “brain” rather than one of its lesser
    organs. James Stillman, the leader of New York’s National City Bank, thought of his firm as a god
    and sometimes as “our mother.” Yet, the obedience Stillman owed his god and his mother did not

    keep him from being “lordly in his manner.”
    The aristocratic and even regal bearing, with its assumption of individual prerogative, came easily

    for the men and women of the upper ten. There were all those kings and queens at the Bradley
    Martin ball. There was the financier E. H. Harriman, who “had the philosophy, the methods of an
    Oriental monarch” His niece, Daisy Harriman, recalled visiting him in his library one evening.
    “Daisy, I have a new plaything” he told her. “I have just bought the Erie [railroad] for five million
    dollars. I think I will call them up now.”

    J. P. Morgan, Harriman’s sometime competitor in buying railroads and organizing the corporate
    world, shared that regal sense of individual entitlement. Although “a great gentleman” Morgan “was
    in his own soul, in his ego, a king “royalty” He exercised the royal prerogative not only in the male
    world of work on Wall Street but in the female domain of the home. Morgan, a family member
    related, “loved to display a frank disregard of the usual rules about babies and assert his entire
    independence of the mother’s and the nurse’s authority – he always took pleasure in doing that, not
    only with his own children but with his grandchildren.” When his first child was born, Morgan had
    her crib taken out of the nursery and set next to his bed, “so that he could look after her himself and
    be perfectly sure that she was well covered up at night.” An intensely religious man, Morgan
    nevertheless revealed his sense of individual authority even when he worshiped God in church. If
    Morgan did not like a hymn, he slammed his hymnal shut, an observer noted. “If he liked the hymn
    but not the tune, he would jingle the coins in his pocket quite audibly as a sign of his disapproval.”

    Upper-class individualism was obviously self-serving and often self-deluding, but it was no
    sham. More than any other group, the upper ten carried individualism proudly into the organized and
    bureaucratized twentieth century. It was just this sort of individualism that their sons learned at
    home, at private school, and then at Harvard, Princeton, and Yale. And it was just this extreme
    individualism that set the upper ten apart from other classes and that guaranteed social tension and
    conflict in the new century.

    Despite their individualism, the upper ten had broken away from much of their Victorian
    heritage. Placing great emphasis on domesticity, Victorianism urged men and women to marry and
    create homes. A wife was expected to devote herself to making that home both a soothing refuge for
    her husband and a nurturing preparation for her sons’ eventual immersion in the economic struggle.
    Unlike Cornelia Bradley Martin’s “domestic” father, however, the upper ten were not so dedicated to
    the home. By the close of the nineteenth century, the wealthy had modified and contravened
    domesticity in striking ways.

    Of course, the rich typically married and created homes. Cornelia Bradley Martin and other
    wealthy women, shunning careers in business or politics, seemingly devoted themselves to the
    domestic ideal as wives and mothers. But these women artfully turned their domestic duty as
    hostesses into quite public roles that earned them fame and notoriety. Cornelia Bradley Martin was
    more of a public figure than her husband. Meanwhile, in a notable departure from Victorian
    tradition, upper-class parents thrust their sons out of the protective cocoon of the home at an early
    age. Rather than bring in tutors to school their boys at home as in the past, many of the wealthy
    began sending their male heirs off to Groton, Choate, St. Paul’s, and other exclusive boarding
    schools in New England.

    The rich were also unusually willing to break up the home altogether. Before the Civil War,
    divorce had been as unthinkable for the wealthy as for middle-class Victorians. But with the rise of
    the industrial upper class after the war, May King Van Rensselaer of New York noted, society
    circles “began to sanction divorces… All at once it became fashionable to divorce your helpmeet.”
    In a nation where, as late as 1920, less than one percent of adults had been divorced, the marriages of

    the rich collapsed with notable frequency. Ten percent of the Americans worth $20 million or more
    who were born between 1830 and 1865 were divorced; of those born between the end of the Civil
    War and the turn of the century, 20 percent were divorced.

    The upper ten broke as well with the attitudes toward work and pleasure that underlay Victorian
    individualism. The Victorians of the mid-nineteenth century believed the individual could be free
    only because he was self-disciplined. Determined to accumulate capital and avoid dissipation, the
    nineteenth-century middle class had glorified hard work, limited leisure, and warily eyed
    consumption. As a boy in a Victorian household, Bradley Martin had duly learned about “the
    importance of work” and “absolute self-denial.” But he and the rest of the upper ten, with so many
    millions of dollars, had no need to work, save, and deny themselves pleasure at the end of the
    nineteenth century. By and large, the upper ten agreed that life should be about pleasure as well as
    the accumulation of wealth. Daisy Harriman even contended that “…the Bradley Martin Balls that
    added to the gaiety of nations and set money in circulation were far more pious enterprises than
    unostentatious hoarding.”

    Admittedly, some of the rich had to work hard to forget their Victorian maxims. “I have never in
    all my life done anything I wanted and cannot now” lamented James Stillman. Plagued by
    headaches, the banker nevertheless drove himself and others to work still harder. His handpicked
    successor at National City Bank, Frank Vanderlip, was much the same. “I had the work
    habit incurably…” Vanderlip confessed. “I did not play. I did not know how to play. I never have
    learned to play.” Nevertheless, Stillman and Vanderlip gradually found the time and money for a
    string of pleasures. Stillman had his fine mansion -”large, heavy, ornate, pillared” -on East Seventy-
    second Street; he had trips to Europe and Palm Beach, an art collection, and one of the earliest
    automobiles. “Like most men, Mr. Stillman wanted the best of everything” an early biographer
    explained almost apologetically, “but without extravagance.” His protégé Vanderlip drew the line at
    buying a yacht but finally took up cigars and bought an estate up the Hudson River.

    Other members of the upper ten took much more quickly to a life of relaxation and pleasure.
    Morgan worked hard but enjoyed “frequent” vacations; Carnegie did not work full-time for most of
    his adult life. This liberation from work was one of the most distinctive features of the culture of the
    upper ten. To many Americans, the rich were, as Thorstein Veblen described them in 1899, The
    Leisure Class.

    The upper ten used their free hours, days, and months to enjoy a host of pleasures: mansions,
    yachts, private railway cars, horses, jewels, and art collections. The homes of the rich suggest how
    the old standards of restraint and frugality had decayed. The typical great mansion required a staff of
    about twenty-four servants and $200,000 or $300,000 a year to maintain. The houses of the four
    grandsons of Cornelius Vanderbilt illustrated the possibilities. The second oldest brother, Willie
    Vanderbilt, and his wife, Alva, had a $2 million “Gothic palace” on the corner of Fifth Avenue and
    Fifty-third Street; the oldest brother, Cornelius II, and his wife, Alice, had a $5 million house on
    Fifth Avenue between Fifty-seventh and Fifty-eighth Streets. At Newport, the Vanderbilt brothers
    had” cottages” -Willie’s “Marble House” patterned after the Temple of the Sun at Baalbek, and
    Cornelius’s 70-room residence, ‘The Breakers” Not to be outdone, the third brother, Frederick, had
    houses in Manhattan and Newport, and a stunning 54-room Italian Renaissance castle up in Hyde
    Park along the Hudson. The most extraordinary Vanderbilt home belonged to the youngest brother,
    George. “Biltmore” completed in the Blue Ridge Mountains of North Carolina in 1895, was a 250
    room chateau on a feudal “barony” of 146,000 acres. Employing more workers than the United
    States Department of Agriculture, “Biltmore” included gardens designed by Frederick Law Olmsted,
    tree nurseries, dairies, reservoirs, schools, a hospital, and a model village.

    While many wealthy New Yorkers pursued pleasure, they kept the pursuit relatively private,
    hidden behind the walls of those mansions on Fifth Avenue. But part of Manhattan’s upper ten
    sought the widest possible publicity. This was the “High Society” of the Bradley Martins. After the
    Civil War, Mrs. William Astor had tried to unify High Society by blending old and new wealth: in
    1888, her aide Ward McAllister had drawn up his famous list of the “400” guests – actually 273 –
    who would fit into the Astor’s ballroom. With Mrs. Astor’s gradual retirement in the 189Os, High
    Society fractured into factions led by Mrs. Ogden Mills, Mrs. Stuyvesant Fish, and other rival
    hostesses who staged extravagant and widely reported dinners, receptions, house parties, and
    cotillions.

    Why should the lavish life-style of the upper ten matter to us? As the Bradley Martins learned, the
    apparent trivialities of balls and parties counted for a great deal in turn-of-the-century America. The
    culture of the upper ten, half perversion and half repudiation of Victorianism, made their wealth and
    power all the more controversial. Elite values would repel the middle class enough to turn
    respectable Victorians into radicals and set off the progressive explosion.

    The gulf between the upper ten and the working class was enormous. Of necessity, working men,

    women, and children lived by a different set of cultural rules that also challenged Victorianism and
    aroused both fear and sympathy in the middle class. The constraints and uncertainties of working-
    class life, low wages, lay-offs, accidents, limited opportunity, early death; made individualism at
    best a wasteful indulgence and at worst a mortal threat. Realizing that they had to depend on one
    another to survive, workers developed a culture of mutualism and reciprocity. At home and at work,
    they taught sometimes harsh lessons about the necessity of self-denial and collective action.

    These were lessons that Rahel Golub learned painfully in the 1890’s. Born in Russia, she came to
    America in 1892 at the age of eleven to help her father in a tailor shop in New York City. Rahel and
    her father lived in a one-room apartment in the crowded Jewish neighborhood of Cherry Street, not
    too many blocks from the Bradley Martins. But Rahel’s world was far away from the lives of the
    Bradley Martins and their friends on Fifth Avenue. As she learned to baste pocket flaps and coat
    edges, she also discovered the rules of life in her new country.

    The center of Rahel Golub’s world was her family. Everything revolved around the family’s
    needs, above all the imperative of reuniting parents and children in America. Rahel and her father
    had to work and save to pay for the rest of the family’s passage to the United States. Against that
    necessity, her needs and wishes, her chance for an education, did not matter at all. Rahel sometimes
    felt the tension between her family and her individuality. “One Saturday” she related, “while
    standing out on the stoop I saw one little girl show a cent to another and boasting that she was going
    to buy candy… It occurred to me that I too would like to have a cent with which to do just as I
    pleased.” So Rahel asked her father for the money. “He looked at me silently for a long moment” she
    recalled. “Then he rose slowly, took out his pocket book, took a cent from it, held it out to me, and
    said with a frown… “Here, and see that this never happens again.” Rahel was stunned: “I felt as if
    the coin were burning my fingers. I handed it back quickly, left the room and walked about in the
    streets. I felt mortally hurt. I felt that I was working from morning till night like a grown up person
    and yet when I wanted one single cent.” When she would not eat that night, her father beat her with a
    twisted towel. “I felt the towel across my back again and again” she would write. “Finally he threw it
    down and said, panting for breath, “Girl, I’ll break you if you don’t change.” I said in my heart, “My
    father, we shall see!”

    Nevertheless, Rahel came to accept the self-denial at the heart of her life and her father’s. “In the
    shop one morning I realized that he had been leaving out of his breakfast the tiny glass of brandy for

    two cents and was eating just the roll” she said. “So I too made my sacrifice. When as usual he gave
    me the apple and the roll, I took the roll but refused the apple. And he did not urge me.” There were
    other sacrifices: Rahel avoided changing jobs because the loss of even one day’s pay would slow her
    family’s arrival.

    As a new “feller hand” in a tailor shop, Rahel worked as hard and as fast as she could to make the
    money needed to bring her mother and siblings to America. The work seemed to be worth her while
    because the shop owner paid by the piece-her output-rather than by the hour. But the older women in
    the shop turned on her for showing that it was possible to produce more goods in less time. They
    thought that her production would encourage the boss to lower the piecework rates he paid them. “I
    knew that I had done almost as much work as the ‘grown-up girls’ and that they did not like me”
    Rahel realized. “I heard Betsy, the head feller hand, talking about’ a snip of a girl coming and taking
    the very bread out of your mouth.” And so Rahel learned to obey the rules of a workplace “family”
    too.

    Rahel and her father discovered other collective bonds. “Each of you alone can do nothing” a
    member of the garment workers’ union told them. “Organize!” They joined the union. Rahel’s father
    also belonged to a mutual aid society; she remembered meetings in their apartment to discuss burial
    plots for the members.

    Rahel’s self-denial paid off. Eventually, she and her father earned the money to bring her mother,
    brother, and sisters to America. But the reunion of the family did not end the demands on her.
    Plagued by poor health that kept her from working, Rahel knew she still had to help: she had to
    marry well. Her parents arranged a match for her with Israel, a young grocer. “It is true that you are
    young” her mother explained, “but you see, father is poor and you are not strong!” By then, Rahel
    understood the logic: “It is clear then; I thought that I must marry… My people could live near and
    get things at cost price, bread, butter, sugar, potatoes. It will be a great help.” But she was reluctant
    to live with “the strange young man and his mother” So Rahel put off the decision. “At last” she
    remembered the scene, “I heard father lay down his spoon and push his chair away from the table a
    little. “Well” he asked in a ‘by the way’ tone, “What have you decided?” It grew so still, even the
    breathing seemed to have stopped. And in this stillness I heard myself say, “Yes.” I did not look up.
    I knew that every face had grown brighter. It was pleasant to know that I was the cause. I had been
    nothing but a sorrow so long.’

    In one way or another, the story of Rahel Golub was repeated over and over in the United States
    at the turn of the century. This was, at least numerically, a working-class nation. In 1900, more than
    half the country, perhaps 36 to 40 million men, women, and children, made up the laboring class that
    performed manual work for wages. They toiled with their hands on docks, roads, and farms, in
    factories, mines, and other people’s houses. They practiced ancient crafts such as tailoring and
    carpentry, and newer arts such as iron molding and metal cutting. They were machine tenders in
    mills and factories, unskilled laborers in towns, farm hands in the countryside, cowboys on the
    range, and domestic servants in Victorian houses. All of them, even the best-paid skilled workers,
    lived circumscribed, vulnerable lives, constrained by low pay and limited opportunity, and menaced
    by unemployment, ill health, and premature death.

    The central fact of working-class life was limited resources. In 1900, wageworkers in
    manufacturing earned an average of $435 for the year; in contrast, middle-class clerical workers in
    railroad and manufacturing firms averaged $1,011, more than twice as much. The lowest working-
    class wages were low indeed: in 1900, anthracite coal miners averaged $340 for the year; domestics,
    $240; and agricultural laborers, only $178 with room and board.

    These numbers alone virtually guaranteed that Victorian individualism was impossible for the

    working class. Many workers simply could not make enough to support themselves, let alone a
    family. In cities, working-class women, crowded into less-skilled jobs and paid less than men,
    struggled to get by on their own. Even working-class men, generally better paid, had trouble making
    ends meet. In Buffalo, New York, where it took from $650 to $772 to support an Italian family of
    five for a year, a laborer could expect to earn only between $364 and $624. The calculus held true
    elsewhere. In Chicago, a typical packinghouse worker could make just 38 percent of the income
    needed to support a family of four in 1910. Meanwhile, in Pittsburgh, working-class fathers
    contributed only about three-quarters of average family income.

    Workers’ wages were uncertain as well as low. Skilled and unskilled alike lived with the almost
    constant threat of unemployment. The cycles of capitalism produced regular upheavals, such as the
    depression of the 189OS that cost Rahel’s father and hundreds of thousands of other workers their
    jobs. Even in prosperous times the working class could not count on year-round employment.
    Common laborers and dockworkers found their jobs measured in days or weeks; they had to hope
    that a boss or superintendent would choose them at the next “shape up” along the docks or at the
    factory gates. Every worker knew that a job might end at any time because of seasonal lulls,
    irregular supplies, and equipment problems.

    If workers survived the threat of unemployment, they still faced the twin specters of injury and
    early death. Every working-class occupation had its difficulties and dangers, from the explosions,
    fires, cave-ins, debilitating “miner’s lung” and other notorious perils of hard-rock mining in the West
    to the “Monday morning sickness” asthma, byssinasis, tuberculosis, and maimings in the textile
    mills of the East. While the upper ten seemed to last into their sixties, hard labor and poor diets aged
    workers quickly. An iron puddler was ‘old at forty” ready for a helper on the job. In Detroit, life
    expectancy for children barn to white-collar workers in 1900 was fifty-three years. Working-class
    children born that year could expect to live to forty eight; the children of Polish immigrants, who
    were mostly unskilled workers, could expect to live only to forty-one.

    By the turn of the twentieth century, few workers had much hope of escaping this cycle of low
    wages, looming unemployment, frequent accidents, and early death. Only marriage delivered
    working-class women from dead-end jobs that seldom led to advancement. Most male workers could
    hope at best only to rise to more skilled manual jobs. With little chance of joining the middle class,
    workers could only interpret Andrew Carnegie’s storied rise into the upper ten as an isolated miracle,
    a freak of nature. “The average wage-earner has made up his mind that he must remain a wage
    earner…” observed the trade union leader John Mitchell. “He understands that working men do not
    evolve into capitalists as boys evolve into men are as caterpillars evolve into butterflies…”

    The constraints and dangers of labor decisively shaped gender roles, childhood, and family
    arrangements for the working class. When so few working-class men could support a family,
    working-class women had to make money. Most labored for pay at same point in their lives. Unlike
    nearly all middle- and upper-class women, working-class women typically took jobs before
    marriage. Many held semiskilled positions in textile mills, garment shops, and box factories. Others
    worked as domestic servants and field hands. However briefly, they entered the mostly male world
    of wage work that few middle- and upper-class women ever experienced. After marriage and
    childbirth, the wives and mothers of same particularly hard-pressed laboring families had no choice
    but to return to the workplace. Even stay-at home working-class women contributed to family
    income by helping husbands with craft work, making jewelry and artificial flowers, taking in
    washing and sewing, keeping animals, or cooking and cleaning for paying boarders.

    Children worked as well. Although same ethnic groups, notably immigrant Jews, placed a high
    value an education, economic realities forced sons and daughters, like Rahel Golub, to leave school

    early. In the South, boys and girls as young as seven and eight labored in the textile mills, first as
    unpaid helpers for their parents and siblings, then as wage earners in their own right. In cities around
    the country, boys got their start on the streets as newsboys, peddlers, junkers, scavengers, even
    thieves. Girls occasionally worked as newsies and peddlers, but, not surprisingly, parents wanted
    their daughters off the streets and in the home, where they helped with cooking, cleaning, childcare,
    handicraft work, and boarders. In one way or another, most working-class children were contributing
    to family income by their mid-teens. Few went to high school.

    In one sense, then, working-class children grew up fast. “I was twelve years old but I wasn’t,”
    recalled Yetta Adelman, a Polish garment worker. “Compared to a child [born] here in the United
    States I was twenty.” In another sense, working-class children grew up quite slowly. Like Rahel’s
    father, working-class parents made sure their sons and daughters did not think too much about
    independence. The crowded conditions of their homes made it that much harder for children to
    develop a sense of their individuality and autonomy. Wage work did little to change this reality. For
    the most part, working-class sons and daughters dutifully turned over their wages to their parents.
    They tended to live with those parents longer-even into their twenties-than did middle- and upper-
    class children. As Italian children in Pittsburgh put it, “you never left your mother and father.”

    That sentiment was no doubt reassuring for working-class husbands and fathers, who were “old
    at forty.” Yet, they lived with the discouraging knowledge that they could not match middle- and
    upper-class men. “A tailor is nothing,” sighed a German immigrant, “without a wife and very often a
    child.” “I left Europe and I was a man” a Russian Jew lamented, “and here I am a what?” America,
    Ukrainian men concluded, is “a woman’s country.” That frustrating thought led some working-class
    men to give up. In the South there were the “mill daddies” idle fathers who abandoned work in the
    textile factories and depended instead on the earnings of their wives and children. For many
    working-class men who continued to labor, life seemed to exact a toll in frustration, drink, and
    domestic violence. Perhaps that was why Rahel Golub’s father, already dependent on his daughter’s
    wages, beat her when she defied his order to eat dinner.

    Immigrant and migrant workers had an especially strong sense of the economic interdependence
    at the heart of working-class family life. Many immigrants came to America with some notion of a
    “family economy” in which each member of the family, under the direction of the male head, con-
    tributed his or her earnings and resources for the benefit of the whole. Like Rahel Golub’s family,
    people came to America in chains of families, as relatives in the United States sent back news and
    steamship tickets to the next immigrants. Once in the New World, immigrants depended on relatives
    to show them the ropes, keep storekeepers from cheating them, and find and teach them work.
    Native-born migrants from the countryside also depended on kin to make the transition to mill towns
    and cities. At every step of the way – from Europe to America, from the country to the city, from
    childhood to adulthood – workers knew that strong mutual ties made life possible in America.

    They worked hard, but their attitudes toward work were far from Victorian. Most workers labored
    out of compulsion, need, ambition, and pride. But given the dangers and indignities of wage labor,
    there was little chance that laboring men would mimic the Victorians and glorify hard work. There
    was also virtually no chance for American workers to mimic the outlook of the upper ten and
    celebrate a life of leisure: laboring men and women spent far too much time on the job for that.
    “Father” asked Rahel Golub soon after her arrival in New York, “does everybody in America live
    like this? Go to work early, come home late, eat and go to sleep? And the next day again work, eat,
    and sleep?” Most workers did. At the turn of the century, employees in the blast furnaces of
    Pittsburgh’s steel mills often toiled twelve hours a day, seven days a week. Around the country, live-
    in domestic servants labored eleven or twelve hours a day, with two half days off a week-and then

    remained “on call” at almost all hours. Only a privileged minority, such as unionized cigar workers,
    lived the dream of an eight-hour day, forty-hour week.

    Despite the limits on their free time and income, many laboring men and women did share with
    the wealthy a powerful attraction to pleasures and objects. Countless immigrant workers were drawn
    to the United States because the country held out the promise of consumer pleasures. “My godfather
    was in Detroit and wrote me that he had paper on the walls, shoes, meat every day, fresh bread, milk,
    water in the house, beer on the corner, soup, and plenty of money” a Polish immigrant recalled.
    “From that time I was crazy to come.” But industrializing America proved to be an expensive place.
    Rents in Pittsburgh were twice as high as in the English manufacturing city of Birmingham. In order
    to save money or even get by in this expensive country, many working-class Americans typically
    had to deny their appetites, just as Rahel gave up her apple at breakfast and her father skipped his
    brandy. Yet, other workers felt that lack of money and opportunity made self-restraint irrelevant.
    Many wage workers, notably single men and Southern plain folk, saw little point in trying to save
    their dollars and deny themselves.

    As a result, a rich culture of release and expressiveness flourished. Some workers shared the
    upper-class obsession with fashion and display. Young laboring women spent precious dollars on
    flashy clothing intended to match or even outdo the upper ten. “If my lady wears a velvet gown, put
    together for her in an East Side sweatshop” a reporter in New York observed in 1898, “may not the
    girl whose fingers fashioned it rejoice her soul by astonishing Grand Street with a copy of it next
    Sunday? My lady’s in velvet, and the East Side girl’s is the cheapest, but it’s the style that counts. In
    this land of equality, shall not one wear what the other wears?” The clothing of young working-class
    women was bold, unconventional, and overstated: “Does Broadway wear a feather? Grand Street
    wears two. Are trailing skirts seen on Fifth Avenue? Grand Street trails its yards with a dignity all its
    own.”

    Workers were known for their boisterous observance of the Fourth of July and their noisy,
    demonstrative behavior in theaters. Public drinking was a further element of this expressive life.
    Amid Victorian abstemiousness, the saloon had emerged as a vital working-class institution by the
    late nineteenth century. The barroom served many functions-meeting place, reading room, music
    hall, ethnic preserve, and male bastion. The saloon was also the place where workers dropped the
    discipline of the workplace and loosened self-control.

    For many workers, sex offered a similar opportunity for expression and release. In towns and
    cities, working-class neighborhoods were associated with the public display of sexuality. Men and
    women made physical contact in the popular dance halls that featured such risqué steps as the hug
    me close, the shiver, the hump-back rag, and the lovers’ walk. “Couples stand very close together” a
    middle-class observer noted, “the girl with her arms around the man’s neck, the man with both his
    arms around the girl or on her hips; their cheeks are pressed close together, their bodies touch each
    other.” Working-class neighborhoods were also the site of brothels and red-light districts. Most
    prostitutes were apparently working-class women desperate for a living wage.

    As it celebrated pleasure and release, the public culture of the working class still embodied the
    mutualism taught at home. The quintessential saloon custom was the practice of treating, in which a
    man bought a round of drinks for his mates and they bought drinks for him. On the giant wheat
    farms of California, rootless, single male migrant harvesters and threshers developed “a strong sense
    of confederation” out of shared coarse humor, hunting, banjo music, cards, and drinking binges.
    Single working women forged their own mutualistic communities in cities such as Chicago. Mutual
    aid associations, like the one Rahel’s father had joined pooled contributions so that individual

    workers and families could cope with unemployment, illness, and death. Trade unions, like the one
    Rahel and her father had joined, celebrated collective action and condemned upper-class
    individualism. “The organization of laborers into Trades Unions” wrote the labor reformer George
    McNeill, “recognizes the fact that mutualism is preferable to individualism.” The middle-class
    journalist Herbert Croly saw workers’ unions the same way. “[The] American laborer… is… far
    more aggressively preoccupied with his class, as contrasted with his individual interests, than are his
    employers,” Croly observed. “He has no respect for the traditional American individualism… His
    own personality is merged in that of the union.” It was a formula for labor strife; and it would help
    fuel the middle-class rebellion to come.

    The nation’s farmers also seemed to share little with the rich at the turn of the century. Like
    the working class, farmers lived precariously; they, too, valued cooperation and practiced a form of
    family economy. Like many workers, farmers had a practical, unromantic view of work, a restrained
    attitude toward leisure, and a wary skepticism about pleasure. But farmers were set apart from
    workers as well as from the rich. Unlike most of the working class, agrarians had not lost the chance
    for economic self-rule. Squeezed by competition and threatened by nature, American agrarians could
    aspire if not to wealth then at least to independence. Unlike workers, farmers ruled over their own
    domain, however small. On a far smaller scale, they could be as lordly as the Stillmans, Harrimans,
    and Morgans. America’s farmers were a cultural hybrid, caught between independence and dire
    need.

    The pressures of agrarian life and culture were starkly apparent in the story of Richard Garland
    and his family. This longtime farmer loved to hear his wife, Belle, sing his favorite song, “O’er the
    Hills in Legions, Boys” with its exuberant, imperial chorus: “When we’ve wood and prairie land, /
    Won by our toil, / We’ll reign like kings in fairy land, / Lords of the soil!” That song, Richard’s son
    Hamlin wrote, “was a directing force in the lives of at least three generations of my pioneering race”
    In the 1850s, the dream of dominion and independence had directed Richard Garland’s father to
    leave the Northeast and strike out west for Wisconsin. There, Richard had mortgaged a 160-acre
    farm of his own in Green’s Coulee, a little valley along the LaCrosse River. His belief in that
    economic and political vision-the dream of a free man, lord of his agricultural domain, the equal of
    his fellow lords was so strong that Richard, like millions of other Northern men, was ready to fight
    for it. The day he paid off his mortgage in 1863, Richard joined the Union Army and went to battle
    the slave-holding, freedom-denying South. After the Civil War, Richard’s vision directed him farther
    and farther west on the nation’s “Middle Border” to ever larger farms and better lands that would
    surely, he believed, make him a true “lord of the soil” Richard moved first to Winneshiek County,
    Minnesota, then to Mitchell County, Iowa, and then on to Brown County in the Dakota Territory in
    the 1880s.

    Richard’s quest for independence depended on the labor of his family. He could not take care of
    his land alone: his Dakota wheat farm sprawled across nearly a thousand acres. Neither could he
    afford to hire all the laborers his land demanded. So Richard turned to his family for help. Hamlin
    remembered how hard his mother worked. “Being a farmer’s wife…” he noted, “meant laboring
    outside any regulation of the hours of toil.” Belle not only managed the Garland household and fed
    her children and her husband; she also cooked and cleaned for his hired hands. As Richard’s farms
    grew larger, Belle had only more “drudgery… cooking, sewing, washing, churning, and nursing the
    sick from time to time” As soon as they were old enough, Richard’s children -Hamlin, Frank,
    Harriet, and Jessie- began to work on the farm. “My father believed in service.” Hamlin explained.
    “He saw nothing unnatural in the regular employment of his children.” At seven Hamlin had

    “regular duties.” “I brought firewood to the kitchen and broke nubbins for the calves and shelled
    corn for the chickens,” he remembered. “In summer Harriet and I drove the cows to pasture, and
    carried’ switchel’ to the men in the hay-fields…” Hamlin soon graduated to more demanding tasks,
    including dragging and plowing.

    Working hard for his father, Hamlin absorbed contradictory messages. On one hand, his father
    taught stern lessons about mutualism and self-denial that Rahel Golub would have found familiar.
    Richard schooled his children to obey his will, not their own. “We were in effect small soldiers…”
    Hamlin recalled. Richard, the Civil War veteran, was their “Commander-in-Chief.” Like Rahel,
    Hamlin had his first real confrontation with his father over the impulse to gratify an individual
    desire. In his teens, Hamlin wanted a fashionable lightweight yellow duster like the one owned by
    his friend John Gammons, who was known as “somewhat of a dandy in matters of toilet.” Richard
    declined. “If you are too warm” he told Hamlin, “take your coat off.’ At first, Hamlin obeyed. But,
    “furious” the boy “rebelled” against “the Commander-in-Chief.” “As I am not only doing a man’s
    work on a boy’s pay but actually superintending the stock and tools, I am entitled to certain
    individual rights in the choice of a hat” he told Richard. “You will wear the hat I provide,” Richard
    insisted. “For the first time in my life I defied him,” Hamlin reported. “He seized me by the arm and
    for a moment we faced each other in silent clash of wills.” “Don’t you strike me” Hamlin warned.
    “You can’t do that any more.” Richard, “after a silent struggle with himself,” handed Hamlin two
    dollars. “Get your own hat,” the farmer told his son, and walked off. Like Rahel, Hamlin had gotten
    his way. And like her, he was shocked at what he had done.

    In a sense, Richard’s” silent struggle” and capitulation were not surprising. Unlike Rahel’s father,
    Hamlin’s wanted independence for his child. Richard wanted Hamlin to follow his own path, to
    grow up and become an independent “lord of the soil.” So, teaching obedience on one hand, Richard
    taught Hamlin independence on the other. “Fight your own battles, my son,” Richard instructed. “If I
    hear of your being licked by a boy of anything like your own size, I’ll give you another when you
    get home.” Hamlin got the message. His father’s farms were, he concluded, “a stern school, the
    school of self-reliance and resolution.

    Across the continent, the nation’s nearly 6 million farmers would easily have recognized that
    “school.” Their farmsteads likely differed from Dick Garland’s. Notably diverse, American
    agriculture ranged from the developing dairy farms of New England and the Mid-Atlantic states to
    the increasingly mechanized grain and hog farms of the Midwest, to the impoverished sharecropping
    cotton and tobacco plots of the South, and on out to the giant wheat farms and cattle ranches of the
    West. About two-thirds of American farmers, like Dick Garland, owned or mortgaged their land.
    The rest were renters, tenants, and sharecroppers who cultivated other people’s land under a
    bewildering variety of agreements. In the North, renters were often young men who would purchase
    land eventually. In the South, tenants and sharecroppers, laboring on unfavorable terms, were less
    likely to become independent. The poorest of the sharecroppers, without animals and tools of their
    own, were virtually as dependent as wage workers. But for all the variations in land, crops, profits,
    and ownership, American agrarians generally shared the central practices and values Hamlin
    Garland learned on his father’s farm.

    Hardly any man or woman could manage to do all the work of a farm alone; a farmer had to have
    help. But as late as 1910, American farmers’ average annual income was only $652. This average
    concealed notable differences. Landowning agrarians – the “progressive” farmers of the North and
    the “yeomen” of the South- typically made more money than sharecroppers and tenants.
    Nevertheless, the great majority of farmers could not afford to hire all the help they needed. And all
    farmers, however wealthy, faced the same threats from nature -the droughts, wind storms, insects,

    illness, and other perils that could doom one harvest and then another. These economic and natural
    realities almost inevitably compelled farmers to develop various forms of mutualism.

    One was the stereotypical “family farm.” “There is a co-operative unity in the farm family that is
    rather striking,” an observer noted. “The whole family is engaged in work that is of common
    interest.” Other rural wives and mothers worked as hard as Belle Garland did. Like her, they saw to
    the farmhands and sometimes took in paying boarders. By tradition, farm wives also raised chickens
    and tended garden plots. The cash these women earned from selling eggs, vegetables, and other
    products was often the only money a farm family saw before the harvest. Farm women frequently
    labored in the family’s fields. Sometimes, they worked for payoff the farm.

    Children also played a critical role in the survival of American farms. “[E]very boy born into a
    farm family was,” one farmer observed, “worth a thousand dollars.” Girls were worth more than a
    little, too. That understanding helped to explain high rural fertility rates -the highest in the nation.
    Most farm women still had several children at the turn of the century. On the frontier farms of South
    Dakota and the poor white farms of the South, families with eight, nine, or ten children were not
    uncommon. Like working-class sons and daughters, the children of farmers had to grow up quickly.
    Like Hamlin and his siblings, other farm children helped out with the chores. Many did wage work.
    On Southern cotton farms, a nine- or ten-year-old was already reckoned a “half-hand” able to pick
    half as much as an adult. As in working-class households, education often had to give way to work.
    The school year was typically shorter in the countryside than in the city. Farm parents were more
    likely to take their children out of school. When Hamlin Garland wanted to stay in school rather than
    work full-time at the age of sixteen, it took his mother’s determined intervention before Richard
    would agree. Even then, Hamlin had to wait until November before his father let him go back to his
    studies. In many farm families, a sixteen year-old would never have gone back at all.

    At times, farmers needed more help than wives, children, and paid farmhands could provide.
    American agrarians had long cooperated with one another through a variety of formal and informal
    arrangements. To secure needed goods and services, rural neighbors established systems of
    borrowing and bartering. This tradition of mutual aid culminated toward the end of the nineteenth
    century in Midwestern threshing” rings” groups of farmers who rented expensive mechanical grain
    threshers together and then worked the large, complicated machines on one another’s farms at
    threshing time. Immigrant farmers had their own forms of cooperation -the churches and mutual-
    benefit associations similar to those of the cities. In the 1870’s, the Patrons of Husbandry, the
    farmers’ organization known as the Grange, tried a number of cooperative efforts. For a couple of
    years in Mitchell County, Iowa, Richard Garland managed one of the thousands of local Grange
    grain elevators, cooperative ventures intended to net farmers better prices than those offered by
    commercial elevator operators. In the 1880s and 189Os, the Farmer’s Alliance developed its own
    cooperatives for purchasing supplies and processing and marketing crops.

    There were limits to cooperation, however. Most of the farmers’ cooperatives collapsed, partly
    because of mismanagement and competition. The cooperatives were also undermined by farmers’
    strong sense of individual self-interest and autonomy. One early supporter of the cooperatives traced
    their failure to “the in-adaptation of rural life and character to the cooperative method of managing
    business.” Farmers tended, he explained, “to gratify their whims” rather than support their own
    cooperatives. As Richard Garland angrily discovered when he managed the Grange elevator in the
    1870S, many farmers would abandon the cooperative whenever they could get” a little more than the
    market price” for their grain somewhere else. “It only shows… how hard it will be to work out any
    reform among the farmers,” he concluded bitterly. “They will never stand together.” His lesson duly
    learned, Richard went back to farming – and his independent ways.

    Richard Garland was typical. “Completeness, individuality, self-dependence, is the ideal life
    which the country should stimulate – a state so desirable for the really developed man,” an agrarian
    advocate maintained in 1890. Isolated by poor roads and poor mail service, farm families felt
    independent. Like Garland, agrarian parents prepared their children for the difficult life ahead by
    encouraging personal toughness and independence. Farmers’ children obviously expected to help
    their parents, but it would have been unusual to hear a son or daughter echo the Italian children of
    Pittsburgh and say “you never left your mother and father.” When Hamlin Garland decided to leave
    home, Richard did not beg or order him to stay. Instead, the “Commander-in-Chief” handed Hamlin
    some travel money. More prosperous Northern farmers in particular tried to prepare their children
    for independence. Recognizing that their sons and daughters might well leave the land, mothers and
    fathers first provided adolescent children with a “room of one’s own,” a separate bedroom; next
    came livestock and plots of land, along with encouragement to make money and manage it for
    themselves.

    Unlike the upper ten, rural couples were highly unlikely to divorce. But this rather Victorian
    commitment to the permanence of marriage did not mean that agrarian husbands and wives were
    committed to the Victorian domestic ideal. Set amid barns, chicken coops, and fields, the American
    farmhouse was no refuge. Rural women contributed much to the family economy. Agrarian fathers
    spent a good deal of time supervising their sons and daughters. As Hamlin Garland and thousands of
    other hardworking farm children could testify, their fathers were hardly remote figures. Men and
    women mixed together more readily in sitting rooms, camp meetings, and picnics than did city
    dwellers. Joining the Grange and the Farmer’s Alliance, women participated in discussion in both
    groups.

    Rural attitudes toward work and leisure were neither Victorian nor working-class. Farm labor was
    as difficult as any working-class occupation and often just as dull – hardly something to glorify.
    Even in the more prosperous North, agriculture was barely mechanized at the turn of the century.
    Farmers, unlike wage workers, could set their own pace much of the time, but that pace was
    demanding. Life on the farm, a commentator noted in 1896, was “drudge, drudge, drudge, from
    daylight to dark, day after day, month after month, year after year.” Most farmers worked a six- or
    seven-day week and took no vacations. Yet, farmers took pleasure in work when they could and just
    accepted it for the rest. ‘They had always worked” the son of a ranch family recalled. “[T]hey
    assumed that work was a condition of life.”

    Although American farmers worked hard, most of them seemed not to be particularly acquisitive.
    Well into the nineteenth century, many farmers, distant from the market, had lived fairly self-
    sufficient lives; they raised what they needed on their land, and bartered for much of the rest. By
    1900, that self-sufficiency had largely ended. Whether they wanted to or not, most farmers now
    produced cash crops for the market. Caught up in a thoroughly commercial enterprise, they needed
    money to get by in turn-of-the-century America. That did not necessarily make them lust for capital,
    however. Farmers might work hard to buy their land and to see that it went to their children, but they
    had no great yearning for riches. The typical farm was no place to make a fortune, in any event.
    Agrarians were not entranced by leisure and pleasure, either. Obviously, hardworking farmers had
    little time for leisure. They tended to spend that time attending meetings and revivals, hunting and
    fishing, and just singing and talking at home. Some agrarians, Southern poor whites in particular,
    liked their liquor; but others practiced temperance or at least preached self-discipline. “My father did
    not believe in serving strong liquor to his men, and seldom treated them to even beer,” Hamlin
    Garland remembered. “While not a teetotaler he was strongly opposed to all that intemperance
    represented.” Agrarians were similarly restrained about sexual pleasure and personal affection.

    “Love was… a forbidden word,” Garland recalled. “You might say, ‘I love pie; but to say ‘I love
    Bettie,’ was mawkish if not actually improper.”

    This sense of restraint helped produce a growing divide between farmers and their hands, who
    zestfully embraced the working-class culture of expressiveness and pleasure. By the turn of the
    century, farmers talked about their wage-earning “labor” with suspicion and contempt. They derided
    these men “as hobos, tramps, and bums” – “men whose lives and aims are not on so high a plain.”
    Farmhands, said Hamlin Garland, “are often creatures with enormous appetites and small remorse,
    men on whom the beauty of nature had very little effect.” For them, time off meant “a visit to town
    and a drunken spree.” Their talk of women and vice districts “shocked and horrified” the young
    Garland: “We had not known that such cruelty, such baseness was in the world and it stood away in
    such violent opposition to the teaching of our fathers and uncles…”

    Farmers were similarly restrained about consumerism. Farmhouses ranged from Southern
    sharecroppers’ pathetic one- or two-room shacks to Northern “progressive” farmers’ framed,
    sometimes bricked houses, with two-gabled roofs. But they were all generally plain. Inside even the
    most prosperous farmhouses, there was not much in the way of objects-some factory-made furniture,
    perhaps a sewing machine, possibly a piano. Even prosperous farmers, proud of their houses, still
    disdained urban showiness. Instead of an ornate, overstuffed parlor, there was a simple sitting room
    with a plain rag carpet. Rural life was unadorned in other ways, too: children had few toys; parents
    had few good clothes. Farmers were simply reluctant to take money away from their barns and
    fields. Even when crop prices were good, Hamlin Garland recalled, “the homes in the neighborhood
    were slow in taking on grace or comfort.”

    So alien in condition and outlook, farmers, workers, and wealthy almost inevitably came into

    conflict. The relentless development of the industrial economy, the increasing spread of news in
    papers and magazines, and the unceasing political contests of a democracy all made the different
    classes constantly aware of one another and generated the many signs of friction in late nineteenth-
    century America. It was an unstable situation – the more so because each group suffered from
    organizational weakness and internal divisions.

    By 1900, farmers’ largest cooperative endeavors, optimistically begun in the Gilded Age, had
    already waxed and waned. The once-mighty Grange numbered only about 98,000 families
    nationwide. Perhaps 30,000 or 40,000 agrarians belonged to other farmers’ organizations. The vote
    totals of the People’s Party, the greatest political expression of agrarianism, had lurched downward
    from a million in the presidential election of 1892 to a mere 50,000 in the national contest of 1900.
    In the South, Populism had provoked costly retaliation: powerful whites were making sure that
    virtually all African-Americans and even some poor white farmers lost the right to cast ballots in
    elections. At the start of the new century, any new agrarian political organization would have to
    draw from a greatly diminished bloc of voters.

    Agrarians were themselves partly to blame for their organizational weakness. Agrarians with
    different kinds of crops did not always care enough about one another’s challenges. Well-to-do
    farmers often had little sympathy for the poorest agrarians. Ethnic and racial prejudice kept farmers
    divided from one another. In the 1890s, nativism ran through the countryside as the American
    Protective Association railed against the malign influence of foreigners and Roman Catholics on the
    nation. But at least farmers were fairly homogeneous ethnically. As late as 1910, immigrants-
    Canadians, Norwegians, Swedes, and, above all, Germans- made up only about 10 percent of farm
    operators. And the immigrants did not differ fundamentally in practices and outlook from native-

    born farmers.
    Race made a starker, more difficult divide across rural America. Only a couple of thousand

    Japanese and several hundred Chinese operated farms, mostly in the West, at the turn of the century.
    They faced substantial hostility and discrimination from whites. Meanwhile, about three-quarters of
    a million African-Americans operated farms, mainly in the South. White prejudice against black
    farmers had seriously weakened the Farmer’s Alliance and the People’s Party. In most cases across
    the South, white and black agrarians had formed separate alliances. When white elites moved to
    disfranchise Southern blacks, too many white farmers were unwilling to defend the African-
    Americans’ right to vote. By 1900, agrarian leaders such as the old Populist Tom Watson of Georgia
    were whipping up racial hatred instead.

    Dogged by organizational weakness and internal division, agrarians also suffered from a more
    general sense of defeat and decline. Richard Garland was fairly typical in this respect. The hard work
    and hybrid rural culture of his family never quite made Richard the independent “lord of the soil” he
    wanted to be. Each year, harvests were too small, or prices too low. Chinch bugs-”pestiferous mites”
    with “ill-smelling crawling bodies”-ate up his crops two years running and drove him out Iowa.
    Drought and low prices plagued him in Dakota. Death struck along the way, too: Harriet died in
    Iowa; Jessie died in Dakota. “Where are the ‘woods and prairie lands’ of our song?” Hamlin asked
    his brother Frank. “Is this the ‘fairy land’ in which we were all to ‘reign like kings’? Doesn’t the
    whole migration of the Garlands… seem a madness?”

    Hamlin was not the only agrarian asking such questions as the 1890s arrived. By the middle of
    that difficult decade, most farmers across the nation, however prosperous, had begun to feel
    diminished. Like Richard Garland, whose farms increased from 160 acres to 300 to 1,000 as he
    moved westward, American agriculture had grown in the late nineteenth century yet somehow
    deteriorated in the process. Despite increases in farms, population, and aggregate wealth, agricultural
    America was falling behind the nation’s urban areas. “While rural conditions are actually no worse
    than they were thirty years ago, relatively they are worse,” noted one observer in 1906. “The cities of
    the United States have moved forward by leaps and bounds.” Though the number of agricultural
    workers increased, the number of non-farm workers increased still faster. Agriculturalists, a majority
    of the gainful workforce as late as 1870, made up only 38 percent of the nations labor by 1900.
    Farms, which accounted for about 40 percent of the nation’s wealth before the Civil War, now
    represented only 16 percent. Even a rise in crop prices in the late 1890s did little to change the
    farmers’ relative economic position: in 1900 non-farm workers averaged $622 in income but farm
    workers averaged only $260.

    The sense of decline powerfully affected younger agrarians. As early as the 1880s and 1890s,
    rural sons and daughters were questioning farm life. Hamlin and Frank Garland did not care for all
    the hard, dull work on their father’s land. For Hamlin, the human toll of farming was unbearable. He
    could not stand to see his mother worn down by all her labors and cares. The death of his sister
    Harriet left Hamlin feeling “like a wounded animal, appalled by weight of despair and sorrow…”

    Meanwhile, Hamlin and Frank had glimpsed another, much more alluring way of life. When their
    father agreed to run the Grange elevator in Mitchell County, Iowa, he moved the family temporarily
    to the town of Osage. For the Garland children, Osage was” a new and shining world, a town world
    where circuses, baseball games and county fairs were events of almost daily occurrence.” Without
    realizing it, Richard had critically weakened his hold on his children. The spectacle of Osage “had…
    far-reaching effects” Hamlin remembered. “It tended to warp us horn our father’s designs. It placed
    the rigorous, filthy drudgery of the farm-yard in sharp contrast with the carefree companionable
    existence led by my friends in the village, and we longed to be of their condition. We had gained our

    first set of comparative ideas, and with them an unrest which was to carry us very far away.”
    Chief among those” comparative ideas” was the attractiveness of a life more devoted to pleasure.

    The Garland children raptly drank in the leisure and consumption of the well-to-do. “We had
    observed… how well Avery Brush’s hock coat fitted and we comprehended something of the elegant
    leisure which the sons and daughters of Wm. Petty’s general store enjoyed” Hamlin wrote. “Over
    against these comforts, these luxurious conditions, we now set our ugly little farmhouse, with its rag
    carpets, its battered furniture, its barren attick, and its hard, rude beds. -All that we possessed seemed
    very cheap and deplorably commonplace.”

    By the time he reached the age of twenty-one, in 1881, Hamlin Garland was animated by a vision
    quite different from the one that had driven his father. Richard had been inspired to go west to live
    out the agrarian dream of independence; Hamlin was inspired to go east to live out an urban dream
    of consumer pleasures. Leaving the farm that year, Hamlin became a writer-a successful one, too,
    with the publication in 1891 of Main- Travelled Roads, a book of six stories about rural life on
    America’s “middle border.” The pattern of Hamlin’s life was set: his career as a middle-class writer
    in Boston, Chicago, and New York City depended on the farm, but he would never be a farmer.
    Neither would Frank, who also left home for an urban life as an actor.

    The Garlands’ exposure to a life-style of leisure and consumerism was not unique. By 1900, farm
    families did not have to move into town to glimpse another way of life. Since the Civil War,
    pioneering mail-order businesses had produced increasingly thick and beguiling catalogs filled with
    clocks, sewing machines, clothes, sporting goods, and other consumer pleasures. Beginning in 1872,
    John Montgomery Ward of Chicago built the first great mail-order business; by the end of the
    century, Sears, Roebuck and Company was successfully challenging Ward’s hold on the rural
    market.

    Paging through the Sears and Ward catalogs, rural sons and daughters found more reasons to
    escape the relative decline of the American farm. Like Hamlin and Frank Garland, young people
    with” a desire for improvement, an ambition for wider success, an impulse to greatness,” kept
    leaving for towns and cities. “Sons were deserting their well-worn fathers, daughters were forgetting
    their tired mothers,” Hamlin concluded. “Families were everywhere breaking up.”

    At the turn of the century, wage workers did not have to worry about the survival of their class.
    As long as industrial capitalism endured, there would be plenty of low-wage manual jobs. But
    workers, like farmers, suffered from organizational weakness and internal division. The union
    movement was still more a promise than a power. Hard times, hostile, employers, and unfriendly
    courts handicapped organized labor in the 1890s. With the gradual return of prosperity, the total
    number of unionized workers shot up from 447,000 in 1897 to 1,125,000 in 1901. Nevertheless,
    unions claimed only a small fraction – less than 10 percent – of the American workforce. Unions had
    barely penetrated broad sectors of the economy and had left numerous working-class occupations
    almost alone – semiskilled factory workers, domestic servants, agricultural laborers. The most
    ambitious attempt to organize across occupational lines, the Knights of Labor, had grown aston-
    ishingly in the 1880s and then collapsed. The largest national labor organization at the turn of the
    century, the American Federation of Labor, consisted almost exclusively of craft unions of male,
    skilled workers.

    Working-class political organization was still less developed. Gilded Age ventures such as the
    Union Labor Party had come and gone. The most promising political vehicle, powered by a form of
    mutualist ideology, was socialism. But in 1900, Eugene V. Debs, the leader of the American
    Railway Union, won only 87,000 votes as the Social Democratic candidate for president. Third-party

    political action was controversial. Many trade unionists held back from partisan endorsements, let
    alone separate political action. And most politically active workers cast ballots for the Republicans
    and Democrats.

    One of the chief obstacles to political action and unionization was the striking diversity of
    American wage earners. In 1900, the majority of the 36 to 40 million members of the working class
    were Protestants. But most of the nation’s 10 million Roman Catholics and several hundred thousand
    Jews were workers. In 1900, 26 million people, more than a third of the population, were immigrants
    or native-born Americans with at least one foreign-born parent; most of this minority belonged to the
    working class. And the immigrant population was surging as the economy revived: the 229,000
    arrivals of 1898 were followed by 449,000 in 1900 and more than a million in 1905. The immigrants
    were becoming more diverse, too, as Southern and Eastern Europeans like Rahel Golub and her
    family increasingly supplanted the German, English, and Irish mainstays of nineteenth-century
    migration. Moreover, the predominantly white working class also included many of the nation’s 10
    million African-Americans, 103,000 Mexicans, 82,000 Chinese, and 25,000 Japanese.

    All these differences of race, ethnicity, and religion produced suspicion, antagonism, and conflict
    among workers. Irishmen harassed Rahel Golub’s father and other Jews on the Lower East Side.
    Around the country, Irish, Polish, and Italian Catholics fought for control of churches, and trade
    unionists kept out blacks. Working-class children quickly learned to respect and perpetuate such
    divisions. In New York City, Jewish boys who strayed into Catholic or Protestant neighborhoods
    discovered what it meant to be “cockalized.” “The enemy kids,” a victim recalled, “threw the Jew to
    the ground, opened his pants, and spat and urinated on his circumcised penis while they shouted
    “Christ killer.’” Racial, ethnic, and religious differences spilled over into occupational differences
    among workers. Skilled “labor aristocrats” prizing their high wages and specialized knowledge,
    often looked down on less-skilled workers. The leaders of the American Federation of Labor, mostly
    skilled craftsmen from German, Irish, or English stock, wanted nothing to do with the unskilled
    workers who came from Eastern and Southern Europe. And occupational differences in turn spilled
    over into gender differences. Despite Rahel Golub’s experience, very few male unionists welcomed
    wage-earning women into their organizations around the country.

    Like farmers, workers also faced the loss of children enticed by other ways of living. Frank
    Capra, born in Sicily a few years after Rahel Golub, passed through New York City with his family
    on the way to Los Angeles early in the new century. Although the California city was three thousand
    miles from the Lower East Side, Capra found the same kind of working-class life that Rahel had
    come to know so well. But Capra could not stand it. “I hated being poor” he said. “Hated being a
    scrounging news kid trapped in the sleazy Sicilian ghetto of Los Angeles… I wanted out. A quick
    out. Capra was sure that education would give him that out. His family, like most working-class
    families, believed jobs were more important than school. “To my family I was a maverick,” he
    recalled. “I was jeered at, scorned, and even beaten.” Finally, Capra’s determination forced a
    compromise. As long as he made money for the family by selling papers and doing odd jobs, he
    could go to school. Daring to “think of myself as another Horatio Alger, the success kid, my own
    rags-to-riches hero,” Frank Capra was on his way-to high school, to Cal Tech, and ultimately to
    wealth and fame as a film director.

    Rahel Golub’s story illustrated another way that workers could lose hold of their children.
    Although Rahel submitted to her parents, she still felt the tension between the demands of family
    and her individuality. How captivating it was to think of one’s self. She remembered the shock of
    reading a Hebrew translation of Charles Dickens’s David Copperfield: “I turned to the first page of
    the story and read the heading of the chapter: ‘I am born.’ Something in these three little words

    appealed to me more than anything I had yet read. I could not have told why, but perhaps it was the
    simplicity and the intimate tone of the first person. I had not yet read anything written in the first
    person.”

    For a long time, that sense of self, of life lived in the first person, was only a faint, private stirring
    within her. To meet her obligation to the family, Rahel continued to work hard when she could and
    then agreed to marry Israel when he asked. Nevertheless, she could not bear the prospect of life with
    this shopkeeper and his mother. Eventually Rahel had the courage to give him back his ring and risk
    her family’s reaction. “Mother cried bitterly,” Rahel remembered, “and father, who had been so
    quiet, so silent all afternoon, went out into the street without saying a word.” Powerful as they were,
    the old ties could not survive the revolt of too many Rahel Golubs and Frank Capras.

    Despite the weaknesses and internal divisions that plagued workers and farmers, the upper ten
    still could not manage to take the lead in a divided America. By 1900, the rich had their own
    problems. The rising number of divorces and other danger signals warned of a basic instability in
    wealthy families. So many rich men and women seemed chronically unhappy. The sons of the upper
    class were particularly unfortunate. Inevitably measured against their famously successful fathers
    and grandfathers, wealthy boys found men like Rockefeller and Morgan a hard act to follow. Not
    only that, but the sons of the upper ten had to perform a tricky balancing act their fathers had been
    spared: these boys and young men had to be conscious of the responsibilities of wealth yet immune
    to its temptations; they had to be loyal to the family yet independent enough to lead it effectively in
    the future. To help meet these challenges, anxious upper-class parents confined Cornelius Vanderbilt
    IV and other boys in the fortress like mansions and secluded boarding schools, safe from the lure to
    spend too much money or to meet unsavory strangers.

    Despite such efforts, or partly because of them, upper-class boys too often became miserable
    young men. “My life was never destined to be quite happy,” said William K. “Willie” Vanderbilt,
    grandson of the Commodore. “It was laid out along lines which I could foresee almost from earliest
    childhood. It has left me with nothing to hope for, with nothing definite to see or strive for.” That
    realization often led to indolence, incapacity, and even self-destruction. John D. Rockefeller, Jr., had
    a nervous breakdown at sixteen. The Bradley Martins’ son Sherman was evidently an alcoholic with
    “an inordinate desire for liquor” “[He] had too much money to spend and too much time to spare.”
    The New York Times reported. “His parents, with an indulgence that he had been accustomed to
    from childhood, permitted him to do pretty much as he pleased… “Falling in with a “dissolute set”
    in fashionable London, Sherman, underage, married a music hall “ballet girl” without his parents’
    knowledge. In December 1894, he left a sanitarium in Hartford, Connecticut and went drinking with
    friends in Manhattan. Collapsing into unconsciousness in a cafe, Sherman died of “apoplexy of the
    brain” the next morning at the age of twenty-five.

    The plight of upper-class children helped turn key members of the upper ten against the frivolous
    life of High Society. Some businessmen, such as Morgan, avoided it as much as possible. One
    upper-class group, descendants of the Knickerbocker founders of New York, self-consciously
    offered an alternative public style. This so-called Faubourg-St. Germain set, including the Van
    Rensselaers and the Roosevelts, rejected ostentation and frivolity and emphasized intellectual culture
    and quiet home life instead. Decidedly “old money” the Faubourg-St. Germain set also objected to
    High Society’s willingness to admit rich new members to its ranks. The Knickerbocker descendants
    believed the upper class would best survive by keeping out unsuitable nouveau riches. The values of
    the Faubourg-St. Germain set were the product of necessity: these people had the pedigrees but not
    the huge fortunes necessary to triumph in High Society. Yet, the Knickerbocker elite also acted out

    of a different sense of what life was all about.
    So did perhaps the two richest New Yorkers at the turn of the century. John D. Rockefeller and

    Andrew Carnegie, migrants to the city, certainly had the money to compete in Society, but both
    abhorred the world of the Bradley Martins. Neither was known for ostentation; indeed, Rockefeller
    was considered “poor in his pleasures.” But both men were also critical of “unostentatious
    hoarding.” Looking for another way of life, the two found it in philanthropy.

    Mostly for religious reasons, Rockefeller had long been a giving man. Driven by Protestant
    beliefs in the stewardship of God’s gifts, he made charitable contributions as soon as he began
    earning money as a teenager in the 1850s. By the 1890s, Rockefeller’s commitment to philanthropy
    also reflected his realization that the pursuit of money and pleasure was ultimately unsatisfying. “I
    know of nothing more despicable and pathetic than a man who devotes all the waking hours of the
    day to making money for money’s sake,” Rockefeller declared. The conversion of money into
    possessions was not very satisfying either. “The novelty of being able to purchase anything one
    wants soon passes, because what people most seek cannot be bought with money,” he said. “As I
    study wealthy men, I can see but one way in which they can secure a real equivalent for money
    spent, and that is to cultivate a taste for giving where the money may produce an effect which will be
    a lasting gratification.”

    Simply because Rockefeller had so much money, it was difficult for him to live up to his
    philanthropic ideals. With the aid of his son, John, Jr., and his adviser, Baptist minister Frederick
    Gates, Rockefeller increasingly made his giving more businesslike, “scientific” and grandiose. In
    fact, he began to dream of a giant philanthropic “trust” to manage his benevolences. With the
    establishment of the Rockefeller Institute for Medical Research in 1901, the General Education
    Board in 1903, the Rockefeller Sanitary Commission in 1909, and ultimately the Rockefeller
    Foundation in 1913, he realized that dream. Giving away hundreds of millions of his wealth to better
    society, Rockefeller believed that other rich men ought to do the same. “[We] have come to the
    period,” he said, “when we can well afford to ask the ablest men to devote more of their time,
    thought, and money to the public well being.”

    Carnegie, meanwhile, had reached the same conclusion by a different route. More than
    Rockefeller, he presented philanthropy as an answer to the fundamental, perhaps intractable
    problems of the industrial upper class. Beginning with two famous articles published in 1889,
    Carnegie laid out what his British publisher titled “The Gospel of Wealth.” While Carnegie defended
    the inequities of industrial capitalism, he recognized both the social isolation of the wealthy and the
    plight of their children. The Scot also freely criticized the lifestyle of Society. “Whatever makes one
    conspicuous offends the canon,” he insisted. “If any family be chiefly known for display, for
    extravagance in home, table, or equipage, for enormous sums ostentatiously spent in any form upon
    itself-if these be its chief distinctions, we have no difficulty in estimating its nature or culture.”
    Noting the hostility between classes in America, he called on the wealthy to use their money for the
    common good. “The problem of our age,” the steel baron wrote, “is the proper administration of
    wealth, that the ties of brotherhood may still bind together the rich and poor in harmonious
    relationship.”

    Carnegie also favored philanthropy for the sake of the rich themselves. If they spent their money
    on ostentatious pleasures, they were guilty of offensive selfishness. If they tried to pass it on to their
    offspring, they were making a terrible blunder. “Why should men leave great fortunes to their
    children?” Carnegie asked. “[The] parent who leaves his son enormous wealth generally deadens the
    talents and energies of the son, and tempts him to lead a less useful and less worthy life than he
    otherwise would…” For the sake of their families, the rich should give their money away. “This,

    then, is held to be the duty of the man of wealth,” Carnegie concluded: “To set an example of
    modest, unostentatious living, shunning display or extravagance; to provide moderately for the
    legitimate wants of those dependent upon him; and, after doing so, to consider all surplus revenues
    which come to him simply as trust funds… for his poorer brethren, bringing to their service his
    superior wisdom, experience, and ability to administer, doing for them better than they would or
    could do for themselves.”

    In promulgating his Gospel of Wealth, Carnegie was not worried whether particular families
    managed to retain their money and upper-class status over the years. At bottom, the steel magnate
    doubted that wealth offered much of a basis for a self-perpetuating class. Unsurprisingly, perhaps,
    this rare example of rags-to-riches mobility insisted “that the greatest and best of our race have
    necessarily been nurtured in the bracing school of poverty – the only school capable of producing the
    supremely great, the genius.” With no son to follow him, Carnegie wanted to promote turnover in
    the membership of the upper ten. Most sons of the rich, he thought, should not hold places of
    authority in their fathers’ companies. Believing the industrial elite needed a steady influx of talented
    men from the lower classes, he made a special effort to elevate poor young workers to partnerships
    in Carnegie Steel. Philanthropy was one more way to ensure that the wealthy, relieved of their
    fortunes, would make way for new blood. To make sure the rich pursued philanthropy in life,
    Carnegie even favored the heresy of inheritance taxes at death: rather than lose their money to the
    government, wealthy men would likely prefer to give it away themselves for the public good.

    Carnegie himself gave his money away with huge donations for higher education, public
    libraries, hospitals, parks, meeting and concert halls, swimming pools, and churches. In 1911, he
    founded the charitable Carnegie Foundation to continue his work. Distributing 90 percent of his
    fortune before his death in 1919, Carnegie lived up to the prescriptions of the Gospel of Wealth. And
    like Rockefeller, he expected the rest of the upper ten to do the same.

    In their way, Carnegie and Rockefeller were the revolutionaries of the upper ten. More than most
    other members of their class, these two men grasped its fundamental problems at the end of the
    nineteenth century. Carnegie in particular understood just how ill-equipped were the wealthy to win
    the battle for authority in America. Rejecting the acquisitive obsession of big businessmen, the
    ostentation of the Bradley Martins, and the genteel withdrawal of the Faubourg-St. Germain set, the
    Gospel of Wealth demanded a radically different approach to life. Carnegie tried to conceal his
    radicalism: philanthropy, he insisted, was only “the further evolution of existing conditions…
    founded upon the present most intense individualism.” But, not unexpectedly, few wealthy New
    Yorkers were ready to follow Carnegie and Rockefeller. High Society held hardly any charitable
    functions at the turn of the century; rich men set up few foundations. Having earned or inherited
    their money, these New Yorkers were going to keep it. Whatever they thought of their sons and
    daughters, the wealthy intended to leave their fortunes to the next generation.

    Two generations had come and gone since the Civil War, but the fundamental problems of the
    upper class remained unresolved. Many of the rich, isolated as they were, did not understand that
    time had run out on their opportunity to take full control of industrializing America. The wealthy
    faced challenges, not only from workers and farmers; the Victorian middle class could no longer
    abide the alien cultures, class conflict, and violence of a divided industrial nation. By the turn of the
    century, middle-class men and women, radicalized and resolute, were ready to sweep aside the upper
    ten and build a new, progressive America.

    As if to reassure the rich, the election of 1900 repeated 1896. Once again, McKinley and Bryan
    battled for the presidency; once again, McKinley won the White House. Yet, in September 1901,
    when the president traveled to the Pan-American Exposition in Buffalo, an anarchist, Leon

    Czolgosz, fired a concealed revolver twice and mortally wounded him. News of the president’s
    assassination shocked the gay partygoers at a costume ball in Newport. As the crowd fell silent and
    the host pulled off his mask, the orchestra began to play the national anthem. “They felt, those
    bearers of America’s ‘greatest’ names,” wrote Cornelius Vanderbilt IV, “that from then on they
    would have to run as fast as they could in order to remain in the same place, in order that the
    nightmare of the future might not become the terror of the present.” The Vanderbilts woke their
    children in the middle of the night, bundled them on board the family yacht, and steamed hurriedly
    to New York to consult bankers and lawyers. Cornelius realized what it all meant for his class. “The
    party” he knew, “was over.”

      Chapter One: Signs of Friction; Portrait of America at Century’s End

    Still stressed from student homework?
    Get quality assistance from academic writers!

    Order your essay today and save 25% with the discount code LAVENDER