economic critical thinking 11

In Chapter 10, Carbaugh Asks, “Can the United States Continue to Run Current Account Deficits Indefinitely?” Since in the long term, the obvious answer is no, perhaps the question should be rephrased to ask the following:

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

·       

Does the United States’ unique position in the world economy allow the country to safely run persistent external deficits?

·        Can persistent U.S. deficits in the current and payments accounts be adjusted without bringing about economic recession or crisis?

In a 4-6 page (12-point font, double-spaced) essay, summarize and critically evaluate the main positions provided on this in Carbaugh’s Chapter 10 and the Deutsche Bank Research piece also assigned as reading for this module. Deutsche Bank Research

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

  

In
te

rn
at

io
na

lt
op

ic
s

E
co

no
m

ic
s

Editor

Stefan Schneider

+49 69 910-31790
stefan-b.schneider@db.com

Technical Assistant
Pia Johnson
+49 69 910-31777
pia.johnson@db.com

Deutsche Bank Research
Frankfurt am Main

Germany

Internet: www.dbresearch.com
E-mail: marketing.dbr@db.com
Fax: +49 69 910-31877

Managing Director
Norbert Walter

  • October 1, 2004
  • Current Issues

    The U.S. balance of payments: wide-
    spread misconceptions and exaggerated
    worries

    • The U.S. balance of payments is by far the most confusing and least
    understood area of the U.S. economy. The confusion is centered around the
    large and rapidly growing deficits. Indeed, the deficit on the current account of
    the balance of payments rose to new records, both in absolute and relative
    terms.

    • These developments created worries and fears regarding the sustainability of
    the external deficits. However, closer examination of the issue shows that the
    worries and fears are exaggerated and, most importantly, there are no short-
    and medium-term solutions because of a number of structural reasons.

    Mieczyslaw Karczmar, +1 212 586-3397 (mkarczmar@aol.com)
    Economic Adviser to DB Research

    Guest authors express their own opinions, which may not necessarily be those of Deutsche Bank
    Research.

    October 1, 2004 Current Issues

    Economics 3

    The U.S. balance of payments is by far the most confusing and least
    understood area of the U.S. economy. The confusion is centered
    around the large and rapidly growing deficits. Indeed, the deficit on
    the current account of the balance of payments rose from USD 474
    billion in 2002 to USD 531 billion in 2003 and is estimated to reach
    over USD 600 billion in 2004 (see table 1). In relative terms, the
    deficits amount to 4.5%, 4.9% and 5.3% of GDP, respectively, in
    those years. Both in absolute and relative terms, these are all-time
    records.

    The sustainability of external deficits
    Persistent and rising external deficits have attracted increasing at-
    tention of politicians, economists and the media. Needless to say,
    the deficits are generally viewed as highly negative for the U.S.
    economy and U.S. financial conditions. The main points of concern
    are:
    • Rising foreign indebtedness that might create financial difficulties

    over time.
    • A potential massive dollar depreciation needed to rectify the

    situation.
    • In an extreme case, a financial crisis as foreigners refuse to fi-

    nance U.S. deficits and switch their capital to other places.
    The media, regardless of their political outlook, have been
    commenting on the U.S. external deficits for quite some time,
    spreading fear and predicting all sorts of calamities, which
    apparently sells newspapers well. About five years ago, in the fall of
    1999, The New York Times ran an article with a pointed headline:
    “The United States sets a record for living beyond its means;” and a
    Barron’s article talked about a current account crisis and a ticking
    time bomb.
    Had these scary predictions materialized, the U.S would have been
    bankrupt by now. But never mind, the fascination with the rising
    deficits continues. A Financial Times article a few weeks ago was
    headlined: “America is now on the comfortable path to ruin.”
    The persistence of external deficits and their presumable negative
    effects have focused the economic debate on the key question. Are
    the deficits sustainable? A generally uniform answer is that not, that
    they are not sustainable. The Federal Reserve chairman Alan
    Greenspan has repeatedly emphasized that he does not believe the
    deficits can go on indefinitely. But he confessed that he does not
    know when will they stop. And he admitted that so far the financial
    markets have coped very well with the global payments imbalances.
    The late Herbert Stein, a great economist with a great sense of hu-
    mor, had famously said that if something cannot go on forever, it will
    stop. The logic of this reasoning is unassailable. However, 2004 will
    be the 29th consecutive year of trade deficits and (disregarding the
    statistical aberration in 1991 when foreign contributions to finance
    the Gulf war produced a small surplus) the 23rd consecutive year of
    current-account deficits. But during this period, the U.S. enjoyed a
    generally prosperous economy, especially during the decade of the
    1990s when the economy went through an unprecedented boom.
    So maybe Stein’s saying should be reversed – if a trend goes on for
    a long time, and it not only does not have any harmful effects but, on
    the contrary, coincides with a period of prosperity, it may well be
    sustainable.
    One-liners aside, there is an apparent conflict between theory and
    empirical evidence. To address the contradiction between theoretical
    and empirical considerations, it is necessary to examine the

    Scary media predictions have so far
    not materialised

    -6.

    0

    -5.

    5

    -5.0

    -4.5

    -4.0

    -3.5

    -3.0

    2000 2001 2002 2003 200

    4

    -700

    -600

    -500

    -400

    -300

    -200

    100

    0

    Current account

    USD bn

    (right)

    % GDP (left)

    -600
    -500
    -400
    -300
    -200

    -100

    0
    100

    70 75 80 85 90 95 00

    Current account &
    trade balance

    Current account
    USD bn

    Trade balance

    Current Issues October 1, 2004

    4 Economics

    following key aspects of the U.S. balance of payments: a) the nature
    and underlying causes of the deficits, b) the financing of the deficits,
    c) main characteristics of U.S. foreign debt, and d) the role of the
    dollar in dealing with the external deficits.

    Main characteristics of U.S. external deficits
    When analyzing the external deficits, it is essential to distinguish
    between cyclical and structural deficits. The cyclical deficits are
    non-controversial and easy to understand. They result from the
    disparity in economic growth between the U.S. and its main trading
    partners, with the U.S. showing stronger growth. This generates
    increased demand for imports while U.S. exports are hampered by
    slower growth abroad.
    Over the past 20 years, the U.S. has shown generally strong eco-
    nomic performance (except for two brief and shallow recessions in
    1991 and 2001), superior to most other industrial countries. It is,
    therefore, not surprising that this coincided with rising trade and
    current-account deficits. Indeed, while in 1983 the current-account
    deficit amounted to 1.1% of GDP, it has risen to about 5% in the last
    two years.
    How long this strongly rising deficit trend would last? It is difficult to
    predict with any certainty. Yet, although the trend has been cyclically
    driven, it has certain permanent characteristics rooted in demo-
    graphic and productivity aspects.
    First, the U.S. is the only major industrial country with growing popu-
    lation. The latest census in 2000 has shown that during the decade
    of the 1990s U.S. population grew by 13.2%, in contrast with stag-
    nating or shrinking populations elsewhere in the industrial world.
    Moreover, although the U.S. population is aging, it is aging less than
    in other main industrial countries – the census revealed, e.g., that
    72.7% of U.S. population was below the age of 50, while the number
    of people in the 35-54 age range, the most productive and highest
    spending segment, increased by 32% in the previous decade.
    Second, the technological revolution of the 1990s was most
    pronounced in the U.S. as it was in America where the
    Schumpeterian “creative destruction” took mostly place. This led to
    strong productivity gains, superior to those in most other nations.
    The combination of population and productivity growth resulted in a
    rising growth potential of the economy. Even allowing for the most
    recent slowdown in productivity growth, potential annual growth of
    the U.S. economy is still estimated at about 3.5%, i.e. about 1%
    higher than in Europe.
    To be sure, there has been an acceleration of the economic expan-
    sion in Japan (even allowing for the most recent slowdown) and
    continuing strong growth in China and the Asian newly industrialized
    countries (NIC). This should boost U.S. exports and possibly arrest
    the inexorable widening of U.S. deficits. But eliminating them, let
    alone turning them around into surpluses, is out of the question in
    the foreseeable future. The reasons lie in the structural deficits.
    The structural deficits draw much less attention than the cyclical
    ones, even though they are at least equally important. Even if the
    disparity in economic growth rates between the U.S. and the rest of
    the world were eliminated, the U.S. would still have trade and
    current-account deficits for the following main reasons.
    First, U.S. income elasticity of imports is higher than foreign income
    elasticity for U.S. exports. This phenomenon is rooted in the general
    openness of the U.S. market, which makes imported goods readily
    available and it makes them available at increasingly competitive

    U.S. has exceptionally high income
    elasticity of imports

    -600
    -500
    -400
    -300
    -200
    -100
    0
    100

    70 75 80 85 90 95 00

    -4

    2

    0
    2
    4

    6

    8

    Current account & real GDP

    Current account
    (right)

    USD bn

    Real GDP
    (left)

    % yoy

    -4

    -2

    0
    2
    4
    6
    8

    10

    90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04

    Nonfarm productivity

    % yoy

    October 1, 2004 Current Issues

    Economics 5

    prices. Moreover, the development of industrial cooperation and
    outsourcing has increased sharply income elasticity of imports, as
    some products or groups of products are no longer produced in the
    U.S. While traditionally the ratio of import growth to GDP growth was
    about 1.7, it is now closer to 2.5 –3.0.
    Second, the proliferation of outsourcing, beginning with the North
    American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) 10 years ago, and now
    extended to India, China and other Asian countries, has almost by
    definition widened the U.S. trade deficit as US products shipped
    abroad return to the US with value added; hence, the value of im-
    ports exceeds that of exports.
    Third, the U.S. dollar’s function as the main reserve currency makes
    the current-account deficit inevitable because of (a) inflow to the
    U.S. of monetary reserves of foreign central banks due to the normal
    accumulation of these reserves, especially in countries with current-
    account surpluses, and (b) occasional interventions in foreign ex-
    change markets by countries trying to resist the appreciation of their
    currencies vis-à-vis the U.S. dollar.
    Of course, this source of financing the U.S. current-account deficits
    is not guaranteed forever. It is hoped that eventually the euro will
    also become a main reserve currency, which would in fact fulfill de
    Gaulle’s idea of breaking the dollar’s hegemony that was at the
    foundation of the concept of a single European currency. But this is
    not likely to happen in the near future. The dollar is still the dominant
    reserve currency as about 65% of global monetary reserves are held
    in dollars.

    The financing of U.S. external deficits
    It is an axiom of the foreign trade theory that a country can run a
    balance of payments deficit only to the extent it can finance it, either
    through borrowing or through depleting its foreign exchange
    reserves.
    In this respect, the U.S. is in an exceptionally advantageous situa-
    tion because it does not need to borrow in a conventional sense.
    The financing comes voluntarily because of the attractiveness of the
    U.S. as an investment destination providing generally higher rates of
    return than obtainable elsewhere; because of the seize, scope,
    openness and liquidity of the U.S. capital markets; and because of
    the dollar’s role as the world’s prime investment, transaction and
    reserve currency. Interest rates are determined by the conditions in
    the U.S. money and capital market rather than dictated by the lend-
    ers. And, unlike most other countries, the U.S. has the ability to fi-
    nance its external deficits in its own currency.
    There is no doubt that this relative easiness in financing is an impor-
    tant factor in sustaining the US trade and current-account deficits.
    Some economists go even further. They contend that it is the financ-
    ing side of the equation, or net capital inflow, that determines the
    current-account deficits. For example, Milton Friedman – in an inter-
    view earlier this year – when asked about the reason for the U.S.
    current-account deficit, responded that it is because foreigners want
    to invest in the U.S. This view was postulated by the Austrian
    economist Böhm-Bawerk a good 100 years ago, stating that it is the
    capital account of the balance of payments which leads the current
    account.
    This view is also represented by William Poole, president of the
    Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. In a paper published in the
    January/February 2004 issue of the Federal Reserve Bank of St.
    Louis Review, Poole – drawing on research of Catherine Mann from
    the Institute for International Economics in Washington – examines

    2
    4
    6
    8
    10

    12

    14

    16

    80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04

    10Y Govt. bond yields

    %
    USA

    Germany

    Current Issues October 1, 2004

    6 Economics

    three different views of the U.S. international imbalance: (a) the
    trade view, in which trade flows are the primary factors and the
    offsetting capital inflows are secondary, (b) the GDP view, in which
    the current-account deficit is perceived as a shortfall between
    domestic investments and domestic savings, and (c) the capital
    flows view, in which the trade and current-account deficits are a
    residual, the result of the capital-account surplus.
    This surplus, in turn, is driven by foreign demand for U.S. assets
    rather than by any structural imbalance in the U.S. economy.
    Needless to say, the capital flow view is the most amenable to the
    sustainability of the U.S. external deficits. There is a legitimate
    concern voiced by some economists that – due to persistent foreign
    demand for U.S. assets – the U.S. has absorbed some 80% of
    international savings in recent years. This may cause a U.S. dollar
    overweight in global portfolios. However, there is no solution in sight
    for this apparent asymmetry in portfolio allocations.
    The financing of U.S. external deficits is an area of the greatest mis-
    conceptions. A popular view held by some economists and the me-
    dia is that foreign investors might refuse to finance the U.S. deficits
    and switch their capital to other places or invest in their own coun-
    tries, which could have dire consequences for the U.S.
    This may indeed happen. But one should keep in mind that
    foreigners invest in the U.S. because they view this as
    advantageous for them, not to do America a favor. Granted, they
    may decide to increase their domestic investments. But as long as
    the U.S. has a large current-account deficit and Japan, China and
    other countries have large surpluses, continuing capital inflow to the
    U.S. is assured.
    It is also true that foreign countries may shift some of their monetary
    reserves to other places. But as long as the U.S. dollar remains the
    pre-eminent reserve currency, this is unlikely because of the limited
    size and scope of other monetary areas. The situation illustrates the
    “exorbitant privilege” – in de Gaulle’s words some 45 years ago –
    the U.S. derives from the dollar’s global role. This enables the U.S.
    to run “deficits without tears” as described by Jacques Rueff, de
    Gaulle’s adviser.
    In short, if someone argues that at some point foreigners might re-
    fuse to continue financing U.S. external deficits, a question must be
    answered – where would they go with their money. The alternatives
    to investing in the U.S. are very limited, indeed.

    The U.S. international indebtedness
    A very important issue in assessing the sustainability of the U.S.
    external deficits is the magnitude and structure of U.S. foreign
    indebtedness, as reflected in annual Commerce Department reports
    on U.S. international investment position (see table 2).1

    As can be seen, net indebtedness reached at the end of 2003 USD
    2.4 trillion or USD 2.6 trillion (depending on the valuation method of
    U.S. and foreign direct investments), i.e. close to 25% of GDP, up
    from a rough equilibrium in 1989. This has caused widespread lam-
    entations that the U.S., the richest country in the world, has become
    within 15 years the biggest debtor in the world.

    1 U.S. international investment position does not exactly represent U.S. foreign debt,

    since it also includes equities and physical capital, but it is a good proxy of the U.S. in-
    ternational indebtedness.

    Current-account deficit can be
    financed by a “structural surplus” in
    the capital account

    Lack of alternative locations for
    investment

    October 1, 2004 Current Issues

    Economics 7

    Such a sharp rise in foreign debt should not be surprising,
    considering the piling up of current-account deficits in recent years.
    What is surprising, though, is that the investment income/payments
    balance has been in surplus (see table 1) despite the large and
    rising debt. How to explain this apparent incongruity?
    The main reason for the surplus in investment income despite the
    rising U.S. indebtedness is that U.S. investments abroad are, in
    aggregate, more profitable than foreign investments in the United
    States.
    This fact is primarily caused by a very large share of foreign official
    assets in the U.S. due to the dollar’s function as the main reserve
    currency. (Private capital flows, as mentioned before, have an oppo-
    site characteristic as foreigners generally enjoy a higher return on
    their investments in the U.S.)
    As can be seen from table 2 (item 18), foreign official assets in the
    U.S. reached USD 1.5 trillion at the end of last year, i.e. 60% or 55%
    of U.S. net indebtedness (depending on the valuation method of
    direct investments). In allocating their monetary reserves, foreign
    central banks are primarily motivated by safety and liquidity rather
    than by the rate of return. They invest these reserves mostly in U.S.
    Treasury bills, which bring them relatively low returns.
    In addition, U.S. currency owned by foreigners, which is practically
    costless, reached USD 318 billion last year (item 27), bringing the
    total of low- or no-cost U.S. liabilities to about 70% of net U.S. debt.
    Moreover, foreign official assets and currency have, by a large, a
    permanent character, similar to demand deposits at commercial
    banks, further easing the burden of U.S. foreign indebtedness.

    The balance of payments and the dollar
    One of the most controversial issues of the U.S. international
    economy is the relationship between the balance of payments and
    the dollar exchange rate. Many economists believe that it is the
    widening of the U.S. current-account deficit that is responsible for
    the dollar decline during the past 2-3 years. Some even go further
    by saying that it would be impossible to eliminate the deficit without
    a massive, prolonged devaluation of the dollar.
    These views are highly questionable. They ignore historic experi-
    ence and they are based on an obsolete theory. If the weakening
    dollar is mainly the result of rising external deficits, how to explain
    the fact that between 1995 and 2001, when the U.S. current-account
    deficit nearly quadrupled, the dollar was on a strongly rising trend.
    Going back another 10 years to 1985, the Plaza Hotel Agreement
    was a major international event aimed at pushing the dollar down,
    with the main underlying objective of shrinking and eventually
    eliminating the U.S. current-account deficit. This did not happen,
    however, and the deficit rose to new highs.
    The main underlying reason for the weak response of trade flows to
    the dollar devaluation is the relative low price elasticity of both sides
    of the U.S. trade balance. On the import side, for the dollar devalua-
    tion to have a full effect on trade flows, two conditions must be ful-
    filled: a) foreign exporters have to raise their prices to offset the cur-
    rency loss, and b) domestic producers competing with imports have
    to keep their prices constant in order to increase their market share
    and shift demand away from imports to domestic production.
    None of these conditions is fulfilled to the full extent. Foreign
    exporters are reluctant to raise their dollar prices in order not to
    jeopardize their competitive position in the huge and lucrative
    American market. They often cut their profit margins and sometimes

    -25

    20

    15

    -10

    -5

    0
    5
    10
    15

    76 81 86 91 96 01

    Net international investment
    position

    % GDP

    0.00

    0.25

    0.50

    0.75

    1.00

    1.25

    70 75 80 85 90 95 00

    Balance of investment income

    % GDP
    -600
    -500
    -400
    -300
    -200
    -100
    0
    100

    80 84 88 92 96 00
    70

    80

    90

    100

    110

    120

    1

    30

    1

    40

    Current account & USD

    Current
    account

    (right)
    USD bn

    USD nominal
    trade-weighted rate (left)

    2000=100

    Current Issues October 1, 2004

    8 Economics

    even run temporary losses, all in order to keep their market shares.
    Labor Department data on import prices clearly show this
    phenomenon. For the past two years non-oil import prices have
    risen only marginally.
    Moreover, even when foreign exporters raise their prices, domestic
    producers competing with imports often raise prices, too, under the
    umbrella of higher import prices, thus defeating the macro-economic
    purpose of devaluation. This had happened on a massive scale in
    the 1985-1995 period when U.S. auto makers did not bother to go
    for higher market shares; they raised their prices, knowing that
    Americans will buy Japanese cars anyway because of their superior
    quality.
    Interestingly, these are not new phenomena, they have been known
    for decades. Weak macro-economic effects of currency devaluation
    were particularly visible during the devaluation of the British pound
    in 1967. Since that time, if anything, devaluation effects have be-
    come weaker still as trade flows shifted further away from commod-
    ity-type trade toward capital equipment.
    Similarly, on the export side, currency changes and the associated
    changes in relative prices have had diminishing results on the trade
    balance. This was especially clear during periods of the dollar ap-
    preciation in the 1980s and 1990s. It did not hamper U.S. exports,
    as theoretically expected. On the contrary, exports were running
    strong since U.S. trade partners were willing to pay higher prices for
    the U.S. technology, know-how and sophisticated capital goods.
    A separate case is the possible revaluation of the Chinese yuan by
    eliminating its fixed exchange rate to the dollar. This is strongly ad-
    vocated by some economists and policymakers in view of the rapidly
    rising U.S. trade deficits with China. But it is dubious that this would
    really happen. The exchange rate of the yuan is a political issue
    rather than an economic one; it is determined by the Chinese Polit-
    bureau, not by market forces.
    The dollar decline during the 2001-2004 period cannot be attributed
    to any large extent to the widening U.S. trade and current-account
    deficits. The main contributing factors were a) exceptionally wide
    interest ride differentials between the U.S. and other industrial
    nations as U.S. rates fell to their lowest levels in over 40 years, b)
    the September 11 events and constant fears of further terrorist
    attacks, and c) a change in the attitude of the U.S. toward the dollar
    as clear signs emerged that the Bush administration is not unhappy
    with the weaker dollar, in contrast with the strong-dollar policy of the
    second Clinton administration.
    All together, a dollar devaluation is not likely to solve the deficit prob-
    lem (if there is one), and may disappoint those who advocate it. On
    the contrary, from the policy standpoint, it may have a negative im-
    pact on the U.S. economy. Considering that it is capital flows rather
    than trade flows that determine the dollar exchange rate, devalua-
    tion might hamper the financing of the deficit without reducing it to
    any large extent.

    Concluding remarks
    The persistence of U.S. external deficits and the associated rise of
    U.S. international debt have led to widespread worries and fears as
    to how long this condition may last and how could it be rectified.
    Closer examination of this issue shows, however, that the worries
    are far from justified and the fears greatly exaggerated, for the fol-
    lowing main reasons:

    -30

    -20

    -10
    0
    10
    20
    30
    40

    80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02

    Exports & USD

    Exports
    % yoy

    USD nominal
    effective exchange rate

    -20

    -15

    -10
    -5
    0
    5
    10
    15
    90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04

    Import prices & USD

    Import prices % yoy

    USD nominal
    effective exchange rate

    October 1, 2004 Current Issues

    Economics 9

    • The primary cause of U.S. trade deficits is disparity of economic
    growth, with the U.S. growing faster than most other industrial
    nations due to demographic and productivity factors. Sure, a
    deep and protracted recession in America could possibly reverse
    the rising deficit trend. But, obviously, the cure would be worse
    than the disease. The U.S. is thus a victim of its own success.
    The deficit is a reflection of U.S. strength not weakness.

    • Even when disregarding the growth disparity, the U.S. would still
    run external deficits for a number of structural reasons, the most
    important of which are: a) high income elasticity of imports, b)
    spreading industrial cooperation and outsourcing, c) the dollar’s
    function as the key global reserve currency.

    • Although the accumulation of current-account deficits raised U.S.
    international debt to about one-quarter of its GDP, the structure
    of the debt is highly advantageous as about 70% of it constitutes
    liabilities to foreign central banks and U.S. currency owned by
    foreigners. Both sources have pretty permanent characteristics
    and, above all, very low cost of financing or are outright costless.

    • The depreciation of the dollar is not likely to change much the
    balance of payments deficit but it may jeopardize its financing.

    So, all together, does the U.S. have a problem with its external
    deficits? If it does, the problem certainly pales in comparison with
    major long-term problems, such as the unfunded liabilities of the
    Social Security system in view of the forthcoming retirement of the
    baby-boom generation, the explosive rise in health-care costs, and
    the growing dependence on oil imports from volatile areas of the
    world.
    Most important, as the paper was trying to demonstrate, if it is a
    problem, there are no immediate solutions of the problem. And to
    quote another Herb Stein’s one-liner, “if there is no solution to a
    problem, there is no problem.”
    Finally, an important mitigating circumstance is that it is mostly
    economists and politicians who worry about the external deficits.
    The general public does not lose sleep over the issue, which only
    attests to the common sense of the American people.

    Mieczyslaw Karczmar, +1 212 586-3397 (mkarczmar@aol.com)
    Economic Adviser to DB Research

    Current Issues October 1, 2004

    10 Economics

    Table 1: U.S. Balance of Payments
    (in billions of dollars)

    I. Current Account 2002 2003 2004*

    Exports of goods 681.8 713.1 791.5
    Imports of goods -1164.7 -1260.7 -1400.2
    Merchandise Trade Balance -482.9 -547.6 -608.7

    Income from services 294.1 307.3 334.3
    Payments for services -232.9 -256.3 -283.4
    Services Balance 61.2 51.0 50.9

    Income from U.S. assets abroad 266.8 294.4 340.8
    Payments on foreign assets in the U.S. -259.6 -261.1 -311.2
    Investment Income/Payments Balance 7.2 33.3 29.6

    Unilateral Transfers -59.4 -67.4 -78.8

    Current-Account Balance -473.9 -530.7 -607.0

    II. Capital (Financial) Account (private)

    Foreign direct investment 72.4 39.9 85.8
    Foreign portfolio investment 385.9 365.4 503.4
    Bank borrowing 96.4 75.6 343.5
    Other 99.5 100.7 85.0
    Capital inflow 654.2 581.6 1017.7

    U.S. direct investment abroad -134.8 -173.8 -216.7
    U.S. portfolio investment abroad 15.9 -72.3 -93.7
    Bank lending -30.3 -10.4 -436.0
    Other -46.4 -32.5 -108.8
    Statistical discrepancy -95.0 -12.0 57.3
    Capital outflow -290.6 -301.0 -797.9

    Capital-Account Balance 363.6 280.6 219.8

    III. Balance of Payments -110.3 -250.1 -387.2

    IV. Official Reserve Transactions

    Decline (+) /Increase (-) in U.S. official reserve assets -3.7 1.5 3.4
    Increase in foreign official assets in the U.S. 114.0 248.6 383.8

    *) Forecast

    Source: US Department of Commerce, own calculation and regroupings

    October 1, 2004 Current Issues

    Economics 11

    Line Type of investment Position, Position
    2002r 2003p

    Net international investment position of the United States:
    1 With direct investment positions at current cost (line 3 less line 16)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..-2,233,018 -2,430,682
    2 With direct investment positions at market value (line 4 less line 17)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..-2,553,407 -2,650,990

    U.S.-owned assets abroad:
    3 With direct investment at current cost (lines 5+6+7)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..6,413,535 7,202,692
    4 With direct investment at market value (lines 5+6+8)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..6,613,320 7,863,968

    5 U.S. official reserve assets……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..158,602 183,577
    6 U.S. Government assets, other than official reserve assets……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..85,309 84,772

    U.S. private assets:

    7 With direct investment at current cost (lines 9+11+14+15)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..6,169,624 6,934,343
    8 With direct investment at market value (lines 10+11+14+15)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..6,369,409 7,595,619

    Direct investment abroad:

    9 At current cost……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..1,839,995 2,069,013
    10 At market value……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..2,039,780 2,730,289
    11 Foreign securities……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..1,846,879 2,474,374
    12 Bonds……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..501,762 502,130
    13 Corporate stocks……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..1,345,117 1,972,244
    14 U.S. claims on unaffiliated foreigners reported by U.S. nonbanking concerns……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..908,024 614,672
    15 U.S. claims reported by U.S. banks, not included elsewhere……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..1,574,726 1,776,284

    Foreign-owned assets in the United States:

    16 With direct investment at current cost (lines 18+19)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..8,646,553 9,633,374
    17 With direct investment at market value (lines 18+20)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..9,166,727 10,514,958

    18 Foreign official assets in the United States……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..1,212,723 1,474,161

    Other foreign assets:
    19 With direct investment at current cost (lines 21+23+24+27+28+29)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..7,433,830 8,159,213
    20 With direct investment at market value (lines 22+23+24+27+28+29)……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..7,954,004 9,040,797

    Direct investment in the United States:

    21 At current cost……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..1,505,171 1,553,955
    22 At market value……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..2,025,345 2,435,539
    23 U.S. Treasury securities……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..457,670 542,542
    24 U.S. securities other than U.S. Treasury securities……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..2,786,647 3,391,050
    25 Corporate and other bonds……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..1,600,414 1,852,971
    26 Corporate stocks……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..1,186,233 1,538,079
    27 U.S. currency……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..301,268 317,908
    28 U.S. liabilities to unaffiliated foreigners reported by U.S. nonbanking concerns……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..864,632 466,543
    29 U.S. liabilities reported by U.S. banks, not included elsewhere……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..1,518,442 1,887,215

    p Preliminary.
    r Revised.

    Source: US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis

    Table 2: International Investment Position of the United States at Yearend, 2002 and 2003
    [Millions of dollars]

    Current Issues
    ISSN 1612-314X

    Topics published on

    The U.S. balance of payments: widespread misconceptions October 1, 2004
    and exaggerated worries

    Japanese cars: sustainable upswing expected September 27, 2004

    Asia outlook: cruising at a good speed September 14, 2004

    Foreign direct investment in China – August 24, 2004
    good prospects for German companies?

    Germany on the way to longer working hours August 10, 2004

    Steel market in China: Constraints check more powerful growth August 6, 2004

    Global outlook: above-trend growth to continue in 2005 July 27, 2004

    Innovation in Germany – Windows of opportunity June 22, 2004

    Consolidation in air transport: in sight at last? June 16, 2004
    Privatisation and regulation of German airports

    Credit derivatives: effects on the stability of financial markets June 9, 2004

    Demographic developments will not spare the public infrastructure June 7, 2004

    Infrastructure as basis for sustainable regional development June 3, 2004

    Available faster
    by e-mail!!!

    © 2004. Publisher: Deutsche Bank AG, DB Research, D-60262 Frankfurt am Main, Federal Republic of Germany, editor and publisher, all rights reserved. When
    quoting please cite “Deutsche Bank Research“.
    The information contained in this publication is derived from carefully selected public sources we believe are reasonable. We do not guarantee its accuracy or
    completeness, and nothing in this report shall be construed to be a representation of such a guarantee. Any opinions expressed reflect the current judgement of
    the author, and do not necessarily reflect the opinion of Deutsche Bank AG or any of its subsidiaries and affiliates. The opinions presented are subject to change
    without notice. Neither Deutsche Bank AG nor its subsidiaries/affiliates accept any responsibility for liabilities arising from use of this document or its contents.
    Deutsche Banc Alex Brown Inc. has accepted responsibility for the distribution of this report in the United States under applicable requirements. Deutsche Bank
    AG London being regulated by the Securities and Futures Authority for the content of its investment banking business in the United Kingdom, and being a member
    of the London Stock Exchange, has, as designated, accepted responsibility for the distribution of this report in the United Kingdom under applicable requirements.
    Deutsche Bank AG, Sydney branch, has accepted responsibility for the distribution of this report in Australia under applicable requirements.
    Printed by: Druck- und Verlagshaus Zarbock GmbH & Co. KG

    ISSN Print: 1612-314X / ISSN Internet and ISSN E-mail: 1612-3158

    All our publications can be accessed, free of charge, on our website www.dbresearch.com.
    You can also register there to receive our publications regularly by e-mail.

    Ordering address for the print version:
    Deutsche Bank Research
    Marketing
    60272 Frankfurt am Main
    Fax: +49 69 910-31877
    E-mail: marketing.dbr@db.com

      October 1, 2004

    • The U.S. balance of payments: widespread misconceptions and exaggerated worries
    • CI-24092004karczmar_doc9
    • October 1, 2004
      The U.S. balance of payments: widespread misconceptions and exaggerated worries

    Still stressed from student homework?
    Get quality assistance from academic writers!

    Order your essay today and save 25% with the discount code LAVENDER