SOCY105A: HOW TO WRITE A PRÉCIS
This quarter, you will write four précis (pronounced “pray-see” in both its singular and plural forms). The goal of a précis is to faithfully reproduce the arguments of an original document while reducing its length to about 1/6 the length of the original. For each assignment, you’ll be producing précis of about two pages (approximately 450-600 words).
Prepare to write your précis:
1. Read the selection carefully.
2. While reading, note the main argument and any supporting material you come across. It can be helpful to underline or highlight important points, or to make notes in a separate notebook.
3. You will need to read the selection multiple times. Try to see new things in every reading.
Write the précis:
1. Begin to work through the text, condensing the material you have read without leaving out any part of the argument. A helpful approach is to start by organizing and underlining the topic sentences in each paragraph throughout the document. Depending on the theorist, it can also be helpful to check the introduction and conclusion to each section or each long paragraph. These will often provide most of your précis’s skeleton.
2. If there are any key terms used by the author of the text, make sure that they are mentioned and indirectly defined within your précis.
3. Write as if you were the author. Do not write, “In this piece, Marx says ____.” In a précis, you actually trying to be Marx, except that you are translating him in such a way that even your non-Sociology friends can understand the text.
A précis, strictly speaking, does not include your own opinions about the work. Instead, it succinctly encapsulates (a) the theoretical content of the work, (b) the research that went into the work (if applicable), (c) the conclusions of the work, and (d) what about the work is important.
Remember:
· This is not a reflection paper or book report – it’s an exact replica of the original, but shorter, and in different words. Think of it as a translation from “more complicated” to “more basic.”
· Try not to quote the text, and limit paraphrasing unless absolutely necessary (that is, unless there’s no other way to say it).
· Don’t add any opinion or new examples.
· Don’t use expressions like, “This passage says…” You don’t want to “stand apart” from the document, but rather, to reproduce its intent, tone, style and mood in different words.
· DO NOT move past the sentence you are working with until you fully understand it, no matter how much background research you have to do in order to understand it.
· Don’t be attached to a sentence once you have written it. Going back to change, re-edit, adjust, add, remove, etc. is part of writing a good précis.
· Practice to simply ignoring/tossing out any text that doesn’t add to your point.
· All work must be edited for grammar, punctuation, spelling, etc., just as you would a formal paper.
SAMPLE PRÉCIS – Marx (in Calhoun)
Start point: middle of pg. 147 (“The worker become all the poorer…)
End point: top of pg. 154 (“…various hitherto unsolved conflicts)
The value of a worker is inversely proportional to the value of the goods that he produces. The worker makes commodities, and is himself a commodity. When a worker’s labor is used to make something, the labor becomes an object that is alienated from the worker. Estranged labor decreases the worker’s value while increasing his dependence on capital. The worker is alienated from the product of his labor, and the product of the worker’s labor diminishes him.
Nature provides the worker with both his means of subsistence and the raw materials he needs to turn his labor into a product. When the worker uses materials from the external world, he objectifies it and compromises his own subsistence. The worker cannot physically sustain himself without the money he earns through work; these earnings further ensure that he will continue to exist physically as a worker. The value of a worker is inversely proportional to the value of the goods that he produces.
Political economy hides the estranged relationship between the worker and production. Labor creates useful goods for those who can consume them while harming those who make them. The most important relationship for us to consider is that of the worker to production. The worker is not only alienated from the product of his labor, but from the process of production. While he is working, the worker must constantly deny his physical and mental preferences. We can tell that labor is coerced because the worker does not participate in it unless he has to in order to satisfy a need. When a worker labors for someone else, he belongs to that person rather than to himself. The worker then feels free only in performing animal functions such as eating, sleeping, and procreating. If estrangement from the object of the worker’s labor is estrangement from a thing, then the worker’s estrangement from the process of laboring is estrangement from himself.
A third form of estrangement is alienation from species-being. Man is a species-being because he understands himself to be a member of a species. Physically, man lives on the products of nature. Estranged labor separates the life of the species from man’s individual life. The activities at which man labors to maintain his physical existence are not estranged. The life-maintaining activities of man and the life-maintaining activities of animal are distinct because man is conscious of these activities as separate from himself. Estranged labor causes alienation by turning this conscious activity into a mere means for existence. Animals produce only to meet an immediate physical need; man produces beyond immediate need. Man is conscious of the existence of species beyond his own. Man can also create objects of beauty. When man is deprived of the object of his production, he is also deprived of his species-life. If nature is taken away from him, he has no advantage over animals: his spontaneous free activity becomes merely a means for survival.
When men are estranged from their own species-nature, they are also estranged from other men. The products and the labor from which men are alienated must belong to other men. Like the product of labor and the process of laboring, these other men are also alien and hostile to the worker. It seems like private property creates alienated labor, but it is actually alienated labor that creates private property through the estrangement of man from other men.
Manifesto of the Communist Party
The history of all hitherto existing society is the history of class
struggles.
Freeman and slave, patrician and plebeian, lord and serf,
guild-master and journeyman, in a word, oppressor and oppressed,
stood in constant opposition to one another, carried
on an uninterrupted, now hidden, now open fight, a fight that
each time ended, either in a revolutionary reconstitution of society
at large, or in the common ruin of the contending classes.
In the earlier epochs of history, we find almost everywhere a
complicated arrangement of society into various orders, a manifold
gradation of social rank. In ancient Rome we have patricians,
knights, plebeians, slaves; in the Middle Ages, feudal
lords, vassals, guild-masters, journeymen, apprentices, serfs; in
almost all of these classes, again, subordinate gradations.
The modern bourgeois society that has sprouted from the ruins
of feudal society has not done away with class antagonisms.
It has but established new classes, new conditions of oppression,
new forms of struggle in place of the old ones.
Our epoch, the epoch of the bourgeoisie, possesses, however,
this distinct feature: it has simplified class antagonisms. Society
as a whole is more and more splitting up into two great
hostile camps, into two great classes directly facing each other
— bourgeoisie and proletariat.
From the serfs of the Middle Ages sprang the chartered
burghers of the earliest towns. From these burgesses the first
elements of the bourgeoisie were developed.
The discovery of America, the rounding of the Cape, opened
up fresh ground for the rising
bourgeoisie.
The East-Indian and
Chinese markets, the colonization of America, trade with the
colonies, the increase in the means of exchange and in
4
commodities generally, gave to commerce, to navigation, to industry,
an impulse never before known, and thereby, to the revolutionary
element in the tottering feudal society, a rapid
development.
The feudal system of industry, in which industrial production
was monopolized by closed guilds, now no longer suffices for
the growing wants of the new markets. The manufacturing system
took its place. The guild-masters were pushed aside by the
manufacturing middle class; division of labor between the different
corporate guilds vanished in the face of division of labor
in each single workshop.
Meantime, the markets kept ever growing, the demand ever
rising. Even manufacturers no longer sufficed. Thereupon,
steam and machinery revolutionized industrial production. The
place of manufacture was taken by the giant, Modern Industry;
the place of the industrial middle class by industrial millionaires,
the leaders of the whole industrial armies, the modern
bourgeois.
Modern industry has established the world market, for which
the discovery of America paved the way. This market has given
an immense development to commerce, to navigation, to communication
by land. This development has, in turn, reacted on
the extension of industry; and in proportion as industry, commerce,
navigation, railways extended, in the same proportion
the bourgeoisie developed, increased its capital, and pushed
into the background every class handed down from the Middle
Ages.
We see, therefore, how the modern bourgeoisie is itself the
product of a long course of development, of a series of revolutions
in the modes of production and of exchange.
Each step in the development of the bourgeoisie was accompanied
by a corresponding political advance in that class. An
oppressed class under the sway of the feudal nobility, an
armed and self-governing association of medieval commune:
here independent urban republic (as in Italy and Germany);
there taxable “third estate” of the monarchy (as in France); afterward,
in the period of manufacturing proper, serving either
the semi-feudal or the absolute monarchy as a counterpoise
against the nobility, and, in fact, cornerstone of the great monarchies
in general — the bourgeoisie has at last, since the
5
establishment of Modern Industry and of the world market,
conquered for itself, in the modern representative state, exclusive
political sway. The executive of the modern state is but
a committee for managing the common affairs of the whole
bourgeoisie.
The bourgeoisie, historically, has played a most revolutionary
part.
The bourgeoisie, wherever it has got the upper hand, has put
an end to all feudal, patriarchal, idyllic relations. It has pitilessly
torn asunder the motley feudal ties that bound man to
his “natural superiors”, and has left no other nexus between
man and man than naked self-interest, than callous “cash payment”.
It has drowned out the most heavenly ecstasies of religious
fervour, of chivalrous enthusiasm, of philistine sentimentalism,
in the icy water of egotistical calculation. It has resolved
personal worth into exchange value, and in place of the
numberless indefeasible chartered freedoms, has set up that
single, unconscionable freedom — Free Trade. In one word, for
exploitation, veiled by religious and political illusions, it has
substituted naked, shameless, direct, brutal exploitation.
The bourgeoisie has stripped of its halo every occupation
hitherto honored and looked up to with reverent awe. It has
converted the physician, the lawyer, the priest, the poet, the
man of science, into its paid wage laborers.
The bourgeoisie has torn away from the family its sentimental
veil, and has reduced the family relation into a mere money
relation.
The bourgeoisie has disclosed how it came to pass that the
brutal display of vigour in the Middle Ages, which reactionaries
so much admire, found its fitting complement in the most slothful
indolence. It has been the first to show what man’s activity
can bring about. It has accomplished wonders far surpassing
Egyptian pyramids, Roman aqueducts, and Gothic cathedrals;
it has conducted expeditions that put in the shade all former
exoduses of nations and crusades.
The bourgeoisie cannot exist without constantly revolutionizing
the instruments of production, and thereby the relations of
production, and with them the whole relations of society. Conservation
of the old modes of production in unaltered form,
was, on the contrary, the first condition of existence for all
6
earlier industrial classes. Constant revolutionizing of production,
uninterrupted disturbance of all social conditions, everlasting
uncertainty and agitation distinguish the bourgeois
epoch from all earlier ones. All fixed, fast frozen relations, with
their train of ancient and venerable prejudices and opinions,
are swept away, all new-formed ones become antiquated before
they can ossify. All that is solid melts into air, all that is
holy is profaned, and man is at last compelled to face with
sober senses his real condition of life and his relations with his
kind.
The need of a constantly expanding market for its products
chases the bourgeoisie over the entire surface of the globe. It
must nestle everywhere, settle everywhere, establish connections
everywhere.
The bourgeoisie has, through its exploitation of the world
market, given a cosmopolitan character to production and consumption
in every country. To the great chagrin of reactionaries,
it has drawn from under the feet of industry the national
ground on which it stood. All old-established national industries
have been destroyed or are daily being destroyed. They
are dislodged by new industries, whose introduction becomes a
life and death question for all civilized nations, by industries
that no longer work up indigenous raw material, but raw material
drawn from the remotest zones; industries whose
products are consumed, not only at home, but in every quarter
of the globe. In place of the old wants, satisfied by the production
of the country, we find new wants, requiring for their satisfaction
the products of distant lands and climes. In place of
the old local and national seclusion and self-sufficiency, we
have intercourse in every direction, universal inter-dependence
of nations. And as in material, so also in intellectual production.
The intellectual creations of individual nations become
common property. National one-sidedness and narrow-mindedness
become more and more impossible, and from the numerous
national and local literatures, there arises a world
literature.
The bourgeoisie, by the rapid improvement of all instruments
of production, by the immensely facilitated means of communication,
draws all, even the most barbarian, nations into civilization.
The cheap prices of commodities are the heavy
7
artillery, with which it batters down all Chinese walls, with
which it forces the barbarians’ intensely obstinate hatred of
foreigners to capitulate. It compels all nations, on pain of extinction,
to adopt the bourgeois mode of production; it compels
them to introduce what it calls civilization into their midst, i.e.,
to become bourgeois themselves. In one word, it creates a
world after its own image.
The bourgeoisie has subjected the country to the rule of the
towns. It has created enormous cities, has greatly increased
the urban population as compared with the rural, and has thus
rescued a considerable part of the population from the idiocy
of rural life. Just as it has made the country dependent on the
towns, so it has made barbarian and semi-barbarian countries
dependent on the civilized ones, nations of peasants on nations
of bourgeois, the East on the West.
The bourgeoisie keeps more and more doing away with the
scattered state of the population, of the means of production,
and of property. It has agglomerated population, centralized
the means of production, and has concentrated property in a
few hands. The necessary consequence of this was political
centralization. Independent, or but loosely connected
provinces, with separate interests, laws, governments, and systems
of taxation, became lumped together into one nation, with
one government, one code of laws, one national class interest,
one frontier, and one customs tariff.
The bourgeoisie, during its rule of scarce one hundred years,
has created more massive and more colossal productive forces
than have all preceding generations together. Subjection of
nature’s forces to man, machinery, application of chemistry to
industry and agriculture, steam navigation, railways, electric
telegraphs, clearing of whole continents for cultivation, canalization
or rivers, whole populations conjured out of the ground
— what earlier century had even a presentiment that such productive
forces slumbered in the lap of social labor?
We see then: the means of production and of exchange, on
whose foundation the bourgeoisie built itself up, were generated
in feudal society. At a certain stage in the development of
these means of production and of exchange, the conditions under
which feudal society produced and exchanged, the feudal
organization of agriculture and manufacturing industry, in one
8
word, the feudal relations of property became no longer compatible
with the already developed productive forces; they became
so many fetters. They had to be burst asunder; they were
burst asunder.