Business Law II

 

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

This project requires you to identify and analyze legal issues and make recommendations based on one or more fact patterns.

Scenario:  Deeper Depths, Inc. is a deep water oil drilling corporation headquartered in Rome, but with oceanic drilling on the east and southern coasts of the U.S.   Deeper Depths transports oil to all parts of the US.  Deeper Depths averages $12 million annual profits and has 300 full-time employees. 

1.  Evaluate and discuss all the administrative regulations that create potential liabilities for Deeper Depths related to its drilling operations and why/how.   

1A.  Analyze and describe several ways Deeper Depth could prevent or minimize potential liabilities related to its drilling operations.

Save Time On Research and Writing
Hire a Pro to Write You a 100% Plagiarism-Free Paper.
Get My Paper

2.  Evaluate and discuss all the administrative regulations that create potential liabilities for Deeper Depths workplace and employee safety.

2A.  Analyze and describe several ways Deeper Depth could prevent or minimize potential liabilities related to its workplace and employees.

Please Note:  Use reference material attached, along with outside sources. Otherwise, limit your analysis and discussion to the topics and assigned resources in weeks 1,2 AND the additional resource below: 

https://www.osha.gov/SLTC/oilgaswelldrilling/index.html

Format

Must use in text citations, and References list.

Must write in depth, comprehensive analysis and explanations to support conclusions.

Use legible 12-point font.

Double Space

Label all parts of assignment questions,

Third person writing is required.  Third person means that there are no words such as “I, me, my, we, or us” (first person writing), nor is there use of “you or your” (second person writing).  If uncertain how to write in the third person, view this link:  

http://www.quickanddirtytips.com/education/grammar/first-second-and-third-person

.

Contractions are not used in business writing, so you are expected NOT to use contractions in writing this assignment. 

The expectation is that you provide a robust use of the course readings attached. When using a source document, the expectation is that the information is cited and referenced with a page or paragraph number.  

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
220

Chapter 5
Administrative Law

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

After reading this chapter, you should be able to do the following:

1. Understand the purpose served by federal administrative

agencies.

2. Know the difference between executive branch agencies and independent

agencies.

3. Understand the political control of agencies by the president and Congress.

4. Describe how agencies make rules and conduct hearings.

5. Describe how courts can be used to challenge administrative rulings.

From the 1930s on, administrative agencies, law, and procedures have virtually remade our government

and much of private life. Every day, business must deal with rules and decisions of state and federal

administrative agencies. Informally, such rules are often called regulations, and they differ (only in their

source) from laws passed by Congress and signed into law by the president. The rules created by agencies

are voluminous: thousands of new regulations pour forth each year. The overarching question of whether

there is too much regulation—or the wrong kind of regulation—of our economic activities is an important

Chapter 5 from Advanced Business Law and the Legal Environment was adapted
by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0

license without attribution as requested by the work’s original creator or licensee. © 2014, The Saylor Foundation.

http://www.saylor.org/site/textbooks/Advanced%20Business%20Law%20and%20the%20Legal%20Environment

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
221

one but well beyond the scope of this chapter, in which we offer an overview of the purpose of

administrative agencies, their structure, and their impact on business.

5.1 Administrative Agencies: Their Structure and
Powers

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. Explain the reasons why we have federal administrative agencies.

2. Explain the difference between executive branch agencies and independent

agencies.

3. Describe the constitutional issue that questions whether administrative agencies

could have authority to make enforceable rules that affect business.

Why Have Administrative Agencies?
The US Constitution mentions only three branches of government: legislative, executive, and judicial

(Articles I, II, and III). There is no mention of agencies in the Constitution, even though federal agencies

are sometimes referred to as “the fourth branch of government.” The Supreme Court has recognized the

legitimacy of federal administrative agencies to make rules that have the same binding effect as

statutes by Congress.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
222

Most commentators note that having agencies with rule-making power is a practical necessity: (1)

Congress does not have the expertise or continuity to develop specialized knowledge in various areas (e.g.,

communications, the environment, aviation). (2) Because of this, it makes sense for Congress to set forth

broad statutory guidance to an agency and delegate authority to the agency to propose rules that further

the statutory purposes. (3) As long as Congress makes this delegating guidance sufficiently clear, it is not

delegating improperly. If Congress’s guidelines are too vague or undefined, it is (in essence) giving away

its constitutional power to some other group, and this it cannot do.

Why Regulate the Economy at All?
The market often does not work properly, as economists often note. Monopolies, for example, happen in

the natural course of human events but are not always desirable. To fix this, well-conceived and

objectively enforced competition law (what is called antitrust law in the United States) is needed.

Negative externalities must be “fixed,” as well. For example, as we see in tort law (Chapter 7 “Introduction

to Tort Law”), people and business organizations often do things that impose costs (damages) on others,

and the legal system will try—through the award of compensatory damages—to make fair adjustments. In

terms of the ideal conditions for a free market, think of tort law as the legal system’s attempt to

compensate for negative externalities: those costs imposed on people who have not voluntarily consented

to bear those costs.

In terms of freedoms to enter or leave the market, the US constitutional guarantees of equal protection

can prevent local, state, and federal governments from imposing discriminatory rules for commerce that

would keep minorities, women, and gay people from full participation in business. For example, if the

small town of Xenophobia, Colorado, passed a law that required all business owners and their employees

to be Christian, heterosexual, and married, the equal protection clause (as well as numerous state and

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
223

federal equal opportunity employment laws) would empower plaintiffs to go to court and have the law

struck down as unconstitutional.

Knowing that information is power, we will see many laws administered by regulatory agencies that seek

to level the playing field of economic competition by requiring disclosure of the most pertinent

information for consumers (consumer protection laws), investors (securities laws), and citizens (e.g., the

toxics release inventory laws in environmental law).

Ideal Conditions for a Free Market
1. There are many buyers and many sellers, and none of them has a substantial share of the market.

2. All buyers and sellers in the market are free to enter the market or leave it.

3. All buyers and all sellers have full and perfect knowledge of what other buyers and sellers are up

to, including knowledge of prices, quantity, and quality of all goods being bought or sold.

4. The goods being sold in the market are similar enough to each other that participants do not have

strong preferences as to which seller or buyer they deal with.

5. The costs and benefits of making or using the goods that are exchanged in the market are borne

only by those who buy or sell those goods and not by third parties or people “external” to the

market transaction. (That is, there are no “externalities.”)

6. All buyers and sellers are utility maximizers; each participant in the market tries to get as much as

possible for as little as possible.

7. There are no parties, institutions, or governmental units regulating the price, quantity, or quality

of any of the goods being bought and sold in the market.

In short, some forms of legislation and regulation are needed to counter a tendency toward consolidation

of economic power ((Reference mayer_1.0-ch48 not found in Book)) and discriminatory attitudes toward

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
224

certain individuals and groups ((Reference mayer_1.0-ch50 not found in Book)) and to insist that people

and companies clean up their own messes and not hide information that would empower voluntary

choices in the free market.

But there are additional reasons to regulate. For example, in economic systems, it is likely for natural

monopolies to occur. These are where one firm can most efficiently supply all of the good or service.

Having duplicate (or triplicate) systems for supplying electricity, for example, would be inefficient, so

most states have a public utilities commission to determine both price and quality of service. This is direct

regulation.

Sometimes destructive competition can result if there is no regulation. Banking and insurance are good

examples of this. Without government regulation of banks (setting standards and methods), open and

fierce competition would result in widespread bank failures. That would erode public confidence in banks

and business generally. The current situation (circa 2011) of six major banks that are “too big to fail” is,

however, an example of destructive noncompetition.

Other market imperfections can yield a demand for regulation. For example, there is a need to regulate

frequencies for public broadcast on radio, television, and other wireless transmissions (for police, fire,

national defense, etc.). Many economists would also list an adequate supply of public goods as something

that must be created by government. On its own, for example, the market would not provide public goods

such as education, a highway system, lighthouses, a military for defense.

True laissez-faire capitalism—a market free from any regulation—would not try to deal with market

imperfections and would also allow people to freely choose products, services, and other arrangements

that historically have been deemed socially unacceptable. These would include making enforceable

contracts for the sale and purchase of persons (slavery), sexual services, “street drugs” such as heroin or

crack cocaine, votes for public office, grades for this course in business law, and even marriage

partnership.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
225

Thus the free market in actual terms—and not in theory—consists of commerce legally constrained by

what is economically desirable and by what is socially desirable as well. Public policy objectives in the

social arena include ensuring equal opportunity in employment, protecting employees from unhealthy or

unsafe work environments, preserving environmental quality and resources, and protecting consumers

from unsafe products. Sometimes these objectives are met by giving individuals statutory rights that can

be used in bringing a complaint (e.g., Title VII of the Civil Rights Act of 1964, for employment

discrimination), and sometimes they are met by creating agencies with the right to investigate and

monitor and enforce statutory law and regulations created to enforce such law (e.g., the Environmental

Protection Agency, for bringing a lawsuit against a polluting company).

History of Federal Agencies
Through the commerce clause in the US Constitution, Congress has the power to regulate trade between

the states and with foreign nations. The earliest federal agency therefore dealt with trucking and railroads,

to literally set the rules of the road for interstate commerce. The first federal agency, the Interstate

Commerce Commission (ICC), was created in 1887. Congress delegated to the ICC the power to enforce

federal laws against railroad rate discrimination and other unfair pricing practices. By the early part of

this century, the ICC gained the power to fix rates. From the 1970s through 1995, however, Congress

passed deregulatory measures, and the ICC was formally abolished in 1995, with its powers transferred to

the Surface Transportation Board.

Beginning with the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) in 1914, Congress has created numerous other

agencies, many of them familiar actors in American government. Today more than eighty-five federal

agencies have jurisdiction to regulate some form of private activity. Most were created since 1930, and

more than a third since 1960. A similar growth has occurred at the state level. Most states now have

dozens of regulatory agencies, many of them overlapping in function with the federal bodies.

Classification of Agencies

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
226

Independent agencies are different from federal executive departments and other executive agencies by

their structural and functional characteristics. Most executive departments have a single director,

administrator, or secretary appointed by the president of the United States. Independent agencies almost

always have a commission or board consisting of five to seven members who share power over the

agency.

The president appoints the commissioners or board subject to Senate confirmation, but they often serve

with staggered terms and often for longer terms than a usual four-year presidential term. They cannot be

removed except for “good cause.” This means that most presidents will not get to appoint all the

commissioners of a given independent agency. Most independent agencies have a statutory requirement

of bipartisan membership on the commission, so the president cannot simply fill vacancies with members

of his own political party.

In addition to the ICC and the FTC, the major independent agencies are the Federal Communications

Commission (1934), Securities and Exchange Commission (1934), National Labor Relations Board (1935),

and Environmental Protection Agency (1970). See Note 5.4 “Ideal Conditions for a Free Market” in the

sidebar.

By contrast, members of executive branch agencies serve at the pleasure of the president and are therefore

far more amenable to political control. One consequence of this distinction is that the rules that

independent agencies promulgate may not be reviewed by the president or his staff—only Congress may

directly overrule them—whereas the White House or officials in the various cabinet departments may

oversee the work of the agencies contained within them (unless specifically denied the power by

Congress).

Powers of Agencies
Agencies have a variety of powers. Many of the original statutes that created them, like the Federal

Communications Act, gave them licensing power. No party can enter into the productive activity covered

by the act without prior license from the agency—for example, no utility can start up a nuclear power

plant unless first approved by the Nuclear Regulatory Commission. In recent years, the move toward

deregulation of the economy has led to diminution of some licensing power. Many agencies also have the

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
227

authority to set the rates charged by companies subject to the agency’s jurisdiction. Finally, the agencies

can regulate business practices. The FTC has general jurisdiction over all business in interstate commerce

to monitor and root out “unfair acts” and “deceptive practices.” The Securities and Exchange Commission

(SEC) oversees the issuance of corporate securities and other investments and monitors the practices of

the stock exchanges.

Unlike courts, administrative agencies are charged with the responsibility of carrying out a specific

assignment or reaching a goal or set of goals. They are not to remain neutral on the various issues of the

day; they must act. They have been given legislative powers because in a society growing ever more

complex, Congress does not know how to legislate with the kind of detail that is necessary, nor would it

have the time to approach all the sectors of society even if it tried. Precisely because they are to do what

general legislative bodies cannot do, agencies are specialized bodies. Through years of experience in

dealing with similar problems they accumulate a body of knowledge that they can apply to accomplish

their statutory duties.

All administrative agencies have two different sorts of personnel. The heads, whether a single

administrator or a collegial body of commissioners, are political appointees and serve for relatively

limited terms. Below them is a more or less permanent staff—the bureaucracy. Much policy making

occurs at the staff level, because these employees are in essential control of gathering facts and presenting

data and argument to the commissioners, who wield the ultimate power of the agencies.

The Constitution and Agencies

Congress can establish an agency through legislation. When Congress gives powers to an agency, the

legislation is known as an enabling act. The concept that Congress can delegate power to an agency is

known as the delegation doctrine. Usually, the agency will have all three kinds of power: executive,

legislative, and judicial. (That is, the agency can set the rules that business must comply with, can

investigate and prosecute those businesses, and can hold administrative hearings for violations of those

rules. They are, in effect, rule maker, prosecutor, and judge.) Because agencies have all three types of

governmental powers, important constitutional questions were asked when Congress first created them.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
228

The most important question was whether Congress was giving away its legislative power. Was the

separation of powers violated if agencies had power to make rules that were equivalent to legislative

statutes?

In 1935, in Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, the Supreme Court overturned the National

Industrial Recovery Act on the ground that the congressional delegation of power was too broad. [1] Under

the law, industry trade groups were granted the authority to devise a code of fair competition for the

entire industry, and these codes became law if approved by the president. No administrative body was

created to scrutinize the arguments for a particular code, to develop evidence, or to test one version of a

code against another. Thus it was unconstitutional for the Congress to transfer all of its legislative powers

to an agency. In later decisions, it was made clear that Congress could delegate some of its legislative

powers, but only if the delegation of authority was not overly broad.

Still, some congressional enabling acts are very broad, such as the enabling legislation for the

Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA), which is given the authority to make rules to

provide for safe and healthful working conditions in US workplaces. Such a broad initiative power gives

OSHA considerable discretion. But, as noted in Section 5.2 “Controlling Administrative Agencies”, there

are both executive and judicial controls over administrative agency activities, as well as ongoing control by

Congress through funding and the continuing oversight of agencies, both in hearings and through

subsequent statutory amendments.

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

Congress creates administrative agencies through enabling acts. In these acts, Congress

must delegate authority by giving the agency some direction as to what it wants the

agency to do. Agencies are usually given broad powers to investigate, set standards

(promulgating regulations), and enforce those standards. Most agencies are executive

branch agencies, but some are independent.

E X E R C I S E S

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
229

1. Explain why Congress needs to delegate rule-making authority to a specialized

agency.

2. Explain why there is any need for interference in the market by means of laws or

regulations.

[1] Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States, 295 US 495 (1935).

5.2 Controlling Administrative Agencies
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. Understand how the president controls administrative agencies.

2. Understand how Congress controls administrative agencies.

3. Understand how the courts can control administrative agencies.

During the course of the past seventy years, a substantial debate has been conducted, often in shrill terms,

about the legitimacy of administrative lawmaking. One criticism is that agencies are “captured” by the

industry they are directed to regulate. Another is that they overregulate, stifling individual initiative and

the ability to compete. During the 1960s and 1970s, a massive outpouring of federal law created many new

agencies and greatly strengthened the hands of existing ones. In the late 1970s during the Carter

administration, Congress began to deregulate American society, and deregulation increased under the

Reagan administration. But the accounting frauds of WorldCom, Enron, and others led to the Sarbanes-

Oxley Act of 2002, and the financial meltdown of 2008 has led to reregulation of the financial sector. It

remains to be seen whether the Deepwater Horizon oil blowout of 2010 will lead to more environmental

regulations or a rethinking on how to make agencies more effective regulators.

Administrative agencies are the focal point of controversy because they are policy-making bodies,

incorporating facets of legislative, executive, and judicial power in a hybrid form that fits uneasily at best

in the framework of American government (see Figure 5.1 “Major Administrative Agencies of the United

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
230

States”). They are necessarily at the center of tugging and hauling by the legislature, the executive branch,

and the judiciary, each of which has different means of exercising political control over them. In early

1990, for example, the Bush administration approved a Food and Drug Administration regulation that

limited disease-prevention claims by food packagers, reversing a position by the Reagan administration in

1987 permitting such claims.

Figure 5.1 Major Administrative Agencies of the United States

Legislative Control

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
231

Congress can always pass a law repealing a regulation that an agency promulgates. Because this is a time-

consuming process that runs counter to the reason for creating administrative bodies, it happens rarely.

Another approach to controlling agencies is to reduce or threaten to reduce their appropriations. By

retaining ultimate control of the purse strings, Congress can exercise considerable informal control over

regulatory policy.

Executive Control
The president (or a governor, for state agencies) can exercise considerable control over agencies that are

part of his cabinet departments and that are not statutorily defined as independent. Federal agencies,

moreover, are subject to the fiscal scrutiny of the Office of Management and Budget (OMB), subject to the

direct control of the president. Agencies are not permitted to go directly to Congress for increases in

budget; these requests must be submitted through the OMB, giving the president indirect leverage over

the continuation of administrators’ programs and policies.

Judicial Review of Agency Actions
Administrative agencies are creatures of law and like everyone else must obey the law. The courts have

jurisdiction to hear claims that the agencies have overstepped their legal authority or have acted in some

unlawful manner.

Courts are unlikely to overturn administrative actions, believing in general that the agencies are better

situated to judge their own jurisdiction and are experts in rulemaking for those matters delegated to them

by Congress. Some agency activities are not reviewable, for a number of reasons. However, after a

business (or some other interested party) has exhausted all administrative remedies, it may seek judicial

review of a final agency decision. The reviewing court is often asked to strike down or modify agency

actions on several possible bases (see Section 5.5.2 “Strategies for Obtaining Judicial Review” on

“Strategies for Obtaining Judicial Review”).

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
232

Administrative agencies are given unusual powers: to legislate, investigate, and

adjudicate. But these powers are limited by executive and legislative controls and by

judicial review.

E X E R C I S E S

1. Find the website of the Consumer Product Safety Commission (CPSC). Identify from

that site a product that has been banned by the CPSC for sale in the United States.

What reasons were given for its exclusion from the US market?

2. What has Congress told the CPSC to do in its enabling act? Is this a clear enough

mandate to guide the agency? What could Congress do if the CPSC does something

that may be outside of the scope of its powers? What can an affected business do?

5.3 The Administrative Procedure Act

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. Understand why the Administrative Procedure Act was needed.

2. Understand how hearings are conducted under the act.

3. Understand how the act affects rulemaking by agencies.

In 1946, Congress enacted the Administrative Procedure Act (APA). This fundamental statute

detailed for all federal administrative agencies how they must function when they are deciding cases or

issuing regulations, the two basic tasks of administration. At the state level, the Model State

Administrative Procedure Act, issued in 1946 and revised in 1961, has been adopted in twenty-eight states

and the District of Columbia; three states have adopted the 1981 revision. The other states have statutes

that resemble the model state act to some degree.

Trial-Type Hearings
Deciding cases is a major task of many agencies. For example, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) is

empowered to charge a company with having violated the Federal Trade Commission Act. Perhaps a seller

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
233

is accused of making deceptive claims in its advertising. Proceeding in a manner similar to a court, staff

counsel will prepare a case against the company, which can defend itself through its lawyers. The case is

tried before an administrative law judge (ALJ), formerly known as an administrative hearing

examiner. The change in nomenclature was made in 1972 to enhance the prestige of ALJs and more

accurately reflect their duties. Although not appointed for life as federal judges are, the ALJ must be free

of assignments inconsistent with the judicial function and is not subject to supervision by anyone in the

agency who carries on an investigative or prosecutorial function.

The accused parties are entitled to receive notice of the issues to be raised, to present evidence, to argue,

to cross-examine, and to appear with their lawyers. Ex parte (eks PAR-tay) communications—contacts

between the ALJ and outsiders or one party when both parties are not present—are prohibited. However,

the usual burden-of-proof standard followed in a civil proceeding in court does not apply: the ALJ is not

bound to decide in favor of that party producing the more persuasive evidence. The rule in most

administrative proceedings is “substantial evidence,” evidence that is not flimsy or weak, but is not

necessarily overwhelming evidence, either. The ALJ in most cases will write an opinion. That opinion is

not the decision of the agency, which can be made only by the commissioners or agency head. In effect,

the ALJ’s opinion is appealed to the commission itself.

Certain types of agency actions that have a direct impact on individuals need not be filtered through a full-

scale hearing. Safety and quality inspections (grading of food, inspection of airplanes) can be made on the

spot by skilled inspectors. Certain licenses can be administered through tests without a hearing (a test for

a driver’s license), and some decisions can be made by election of those affected (labor union elections).

Rulemaking
Trial-type hearings generally impose on particular parties liabilities based on past or present facts.

Because these cases will serve as precedents, they are a partial guide to future conduct by others. But they

do not directly apply to nonparties, who may argue in a subsequent case that their conduct does not fit

within the holding announced in the case. Agencies can affect future conduct far more directly by

announcing rules that apply to all who come within the agency’s jurisdiction.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
234

The acts creating most of the major federal agencies expressly grant them authority to engage in

rulemaking. This means, in essence, authority to legislate. The outpouring of federal regulations has been

immense. The APA directs agencies about to engage in rulemaking to give notice in

the Federal Register of their intent to do so. The Federal Register is published daily, Monday through

Friday, in Washington, DC, and contains notice of various actions, including announcements of proposed

rulemaking and regulations as adopted. The notice must specify the time, place, and nature of the

rulemaking and offer a description of the proposed rule or the issues involved. Any interested person or

organization is entitled to participate by submitting written “data, views or arguments.” Agencies are not

legally required to air debate over proposed rules, though they often do so.

The procedure just described is known as “informal” rulemaking. A different procedure is required for

“formal” rulemaking, defined as those instances in which the enabling legislation directs an agency to

make rules “on the record after opportunity for an agency hearing.” When engaging in formal rulemaking,

agencies must hold an adversary hearing.

Administrative regulations are not legally binding unless they are published. Agencies must publish in

the Federal Register the text of final regulations, which ordinarily do not become effective until thirty

days later. Every year the annual output of regulations is collected and reprinted in

the Code of Federal Regulations, a multivolume paperback series containing all federal rules and

regulations keyed to the fifty titles of the US Code (the compilation ofall federal statutes enacted by

Congress and grouped according to subject).

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

Agencies make rules that have the same effect as laws passed by Congress and the

president. But such rules (regulations) must allow for full participation by

interested parties. The Administrative Procedure Act (APA) governs both

rulemaking and the agency enforcement of regulations, and it provides a process

for fair hearings.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
235

E X E R C I S E S

1. Go to http://www.regulations.gov/search/Regs/home.html#home. Browse

the site. Find a topic that interests you, and then find a proposed regulation.

Notice how comments on the proposed rule are invited.

2. Why would there be a trial by an administrative agency? Describe the process.

5.4 Administrative Burdens on Business Operations

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. Describe the paperwork burden imposed by administrative agencies.

2. Explain why agencies have the power of investigation, and what limits there

are to that power.

3. Explain the need for the Freedom of Information Act and how it works in the

US legal system.

The Paperwork Burden
The administrative process is not frictionless. The interplay between government agency and private

enterprise can burden business operations in a number of ways. Several of these are noted in this section.

Deciding whether and how to act are not decisions that government agencies reach out of the blue. They

rely heavily on information garnered from business itself. Dozens of federal agencies require corporations

to keep hundreds of types of records and to file numerous periodic reports. The Commission on Federal

Paperwork, established during the Ford administration to consider ways of reducing the paperwork

burden, estimated in its final report in 1977 that the total annual cost of federal paperwork amounted to

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
236

$50 billion and that the 10,000 largest business enterprises spent $10 billion annually on paperwork

alone. The paperwork involved in licensing a single nuclear power plant, the commission said, costs

upward of $15 million.

Not surprisingly, therefore, businesses have sought ways of avoiding requests for data. Since the 1940s,

the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) has collected economic data on corporate performance from

individual companies for statistical purposes. As long as each company engages in a single line of

business, data are comparable. When the era of conglomerates began in the 1970s, with widely divergent

types of businesses brought together under the roof of a single corporate parent, the data became useless

for purposes of examining the competitive behavior of different industries. So the FTC ordered dozens of

large companies to break out their economic information according to each line of business that they

carried on. The companies resisted, but the US Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit,

where much of the litigation over federal administrative action is decided, directed the companies to

comply with the commission’s order, holding that the Federal Trade Commission Act clearly permits the

agency to collect information for investigatory purposes. [1]

In 1980, responding to cries that businesses, individuals, and state and local governments were being

swamped by federal demands for paperwork, Congress enacted the Paperwork Reduction Act. It gives

power to the federal Office of Management and Budget (OMB) to develop uniform policies for

coordinating the gathering, storage, and transmission of all the millions of reports flowing in each year to

the scores of federal departments and agencies requesting information. These reports include tax and

Medicare forms, financial loan and job applications, questionnaires of all sorts, compliance reports, and

tax and business records. The OMB was given the power also to determine whether new kinds of

information are needed. In effect, any agency that wants to collect new information from outside must

obtain the OMB’s approval.

Inspections
No one likes surprise inspections. A section of the Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970 empowers

agents of the Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA) to search work areas for safety

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
237

hazards and for violations of OSHA regulations. The act does not specify whether inspectors are required

to obtain search warrants, required under the Fourth Amendment in criminal cases. For many years, the

government insisted that surprise inspections are not unreasonable and that the time required to obtain a

warrant would defeat the surprise element. The Supreme Court finally ruled squarely on the issue in 1978.

In Marshall v. Barlow’s, Inc., the court held that no less than private individuals, businesses are entitled

to refuse police demands to search the premises unless a court has issued a search warrant. [2]

But where a certain type of business is closely regulated, surprise inspections are the norm, and no

warrant is required. For example, businesses with liquor licenses that might sell to minors are subject to

both overt and covert inspections (e.g., an undercover officer may “search” a liquor store by sending an

underage patron to the store). Or a junkyard that specializes in automobiles and automobile parts may

also be subject to surprise inspections, on the rationale that junkyards are highly likely to be active in the

resale of stolen autos or stolen auto parts. [3]

It is also possible for inspections to take place without a search warrant and without the permission of the

business. For example, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) wished to inspect parts of the Dow

Chemical facility in Midland, Michigan, without the benefit of warrant. When they were refused, agents of

the EPA obtained a fairly advanced aerial mapping camera and rented an airplane to fly over the Dow

facility. Dow went to court for a restraining order against the EPA and a request to have the EPA turn over

all photographs taken. But the Supreme Court ruled that the areas photographed were “open fields” and

not subject to the protections of the Fourth Amendment. [4]

Access to Business Information in Government Files
In 1966, Congress enacted the Freedom of Information Act (FOIA), opening up to the citizenry many of

the files of the government. (The act was amended in 1974 and again in 1976 to overcome a tendency of

many agencies to stall or refuse access to their files.) Under the FOIA, any person has a legally enforceable

right of access to all government documents, with nine specific exceptions, such as classified military

intelligence, medical files, and trade secrets and commercial or financial information if “obtained from a

person and privileged or confidential.” Without the trade-secret and financial-information exemptions,

business competitors could, merely by requesting it, obtain highly sensitive competitive information

sitting in government files.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
238

A federal agency is required under the FOIA to respond to a document request within ten days. But in

practice, months or even years may pass before the government actually responds to an FOIA request.

Requesters must also pay the cost of locating and copying the records. Moreover, not all documents are

available for public inspection. Along with the trade-secret and financial-information exemptions, the

FOIA specifically exempts the following:

records required by executive order of the president to be kept secret in the interest of national

defense or public policy

records related solely to the internal personnel rules and practice of an agency

records exempted from disclosure by another statute

interagency memos or decisions reflecting the deliberative process

personnel files and other files that if disclosed, would constitute an unwarranted invasion of

personal privacy

information compiled for law enforcement purposes

geological information concerning wells

Note that the government may provide such information but is not required to provide such information;

it retains discretion to provide information or not.

Regulated companies are often required to submit confidential information to the government. For these

companies, submitting such information presents a danger under the FOIA of disclosure to competitors.

To protect information from disclosure, the company is well advised to mark each document as privileged

and confidential so that government officials reviewing it for a FOIA request will not automatically

disclose it. Most agencies notify a company whose data they are about to disclose. But these practices are

not legally required under the FOIA.

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
239

Government agencies, in order to do their jobs, collect a great deal of information

from businesses. This can range from routine paperwork (often burdensome) to

inspections, those with warrants and those without. Surprise inspections are

allowed for closely regulated industries but are subject to Fourth Amendment

requirements in general. Some information collected by agencies can be accessed

using the Freedom of Information Act.

E X E R C I S E S

1. Give two examples of a closely regulated industry. Explain why some

warrantless searches would be allowed.

2. Find out why FOIA requests often take months or years to accomplish.

[1] In re FTC Line of Business Report Litigation, 595 F.2d 685 (D.C. Cir. 1978).

[2] Marshall v. Barlow’s, Inc., 436 US 307 (1978).

[3] New York v. Burger, 482 US 691 (1987).

[4] Dow Chemical Co. v. United States Environmental Protection Agency, 476 US 227 (1986).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
240

5.5 The Scope of Judicial Review

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. Describe the “exhaustion of remedies” requirement.

2. Detail various strategies for obtaining judicial review of agency rules.

3. Explain under what circumstances it is possible to sue the government.

Neither an administrative agency’s adjudication nor its issuance of a regulation is necessarily final. Most

federal agency decisions are appealable to the federal circuit courts. To get to court, the appellant must

overcome numerous complex hurdles. He or she must have standing—that is, be in some sense directly

affected by the decision or regulation. The case must be ripe for review; administrative remedies such as

further appeal within the agency must have been exhausted.

Exhaustion of Administrative Remedies
Before you can complain to court about an agency’s action, you must first try to get the agency to

reconsider its action. Generally, you must have asked for a hearing at the hearing examiner level, there

must have been a decision reached that was unfavorable to you, and you must have appealed the decision

to the full board. The full board must rule against you, and only then will you be heard by a court. The

broadest exception to this exhaustion of administrative remedies requirement is if the agency had no

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
241

authority to issue the rule or regulation in the first place, if exhaustion of remedies would be impractical

or futile, or if great harm would happen should the rule or regulation continue to apply. Also, if the agency

is not acting in good faith, the courts will hear an appeal without exhaustion.

Strategies for Obtaining Judicial Review
Once these obstacles are cleared, the court may look at one of a series of claims. The appellant might

assert that the agency’s action was ultra vires (UL-truh VI-reez)—beyond the scope of its authority as set

down in the statute. This attack is rarely successful. A somewhat more successful claim is that the agency

did not abide by its own procedures or those imposed upon it by the Administrative Procedure Act.

In formal rulemaking, the appellant also might insist that the agency lacked substantial evidence for the

determination that it made. If there is virtually no evidence to support the agency’s findings, the court

may reverse. But findings of fact are not often overturned by the courts.

Likewise, there has long been a presumption that when an agency issues a regulation, it has the authority

to do so: those opposing the regulation must bear a heavy burden in court to upset it. This is not a

surprising rule, for otherwise courts, not administrators, would be the authors of regulations.

Nevertheless, regulations cannot exceed the scope of the authority conferred by Congress on the agency.

In an important 1981 case before the Supreme Court, the issue was whether the secretary of labor, acting

through the Occupational Health and Safety Administration (OSHA), could lawfully issue a standard

limiting exposure to cotton dust in the workplace without first undertaking a cost-benefit analysis. A

dozen cotton textile manufacturers and the American Textile Manufacturers Institute, representing 175

companies, asserted that the cotton dust standard was unlawful because it did not rationally relate the

benefits to be derived from the standard to the costs that the standard would impose. See Section 5.6

“Cases”, American Textile Manufacturers Institute v. Donovan.

In summary, then, an individual or a company may (after exhaustion of administrative remedies)

challenge agency action where such action is the following:

not in accordance with the agency’s scope of authority

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
242

not in accordance with the US Constitution or the Administrative Procedure Act

not in accordance with the substantial evidence test

unwarranted by the facts

arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in accord with the law

Section 706 of the Administrative Procedure Act sets out those standards. While it is difficult to show that

an agency’s action is arbitrary and capricious, there are cases that have so held. For example, after the

Reagan administration set aside a Carter administration rule from the National Highway Traffic and

Safety Administration on passive restraints in automobiles, State Farm and other insurance companies

challenged the reversal as arbitrary and capricious. Examining the record, the Supreme Court found that

the agency had failed to state enough reasons for its reversal and required the agency to review the record

and the rule and provide adequate reasons for its reversal. State Farm and other insurance companies

thus gained a legal benefit by keeping an agency rule that placed costs on automakers for increased

passenger safety and potentially reducing the number of injury claims from those it had insured. [1]

Suing the Government
In the modern administrative state, the range of government activity is immense, and administrative

agencies frequently get in the way of business enterprise. Often, bureaucratic involvement is wholly

legitimate, compelled by law; sometimes, however, agencies or government officials may overstep their

bounds, in a fit of zeal or spite. What recourse does the private individual or company have?

Mainly for historical reasons, it has always been more difficult to sue the government than to sue private

individuals or corporations. For one thing, the government has long had recourse to the doctrine of

sovereign immunity as a shield against lawsuits. Yet in 1976, Congress amended the Administrative

Procedure Act to waive any federal claim to sovereign immunity in cases of injunctive or other

nonmonetary relief. Earlier, in 1946, in the Federal Tort Claims Act, Congress had waived sovereign

immunity of the federal government for most tort claims for money damages, although the act contains

several exceptions for specific agencies (e.g., one cannot sue for injuries resulting from fiscal operations of

the Treasury Department or for injuries stemming from activities of the military in wartime). The act also

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
243

contains a major exception for claims “based upon [an official’s] exercise or performance or the failure to

exercise or perform a discretionary function or duty.” This exception prevents suits against parole boards

for paroling dangerous criminals who then kill or maim in the course of another crime and suits against

officials whose decision to ship explosive materials by public carrier leads to mass deaths and injuries

following an explosion en route. [2]

In recent years, the Supreme Court has been stripping away the traditional immunity enjoyed by many

government officials against personal suits. Some government employees—judges, prosecutors,

legislators, and the president, for example—have absolute immunity against suit for official actions. But

many public administrators and government employees have at best a qualified immunity. Under a

provision of the Civil Rights Act of 1871 (so-called Section 1983 actions), state officials can be sued in

federal court for money damages whenever “under color of any state law” they deprive anyone of his

rights under the Constitution or federal law. In Bivens v. Six Unknown Federal Narcotics Agents, the

Supreme Court held that federal agents may be sued for violating the plaintiff’s Fourth Amendment rights

against an unlawful search of his home. [3] Subsequent cases have followed this logic to permit suits for

violations of other constitutional provisions. This area of the law is in a state of flux, and it is likely to

continue to evolve.

Sometimes damage is done to an individual or business because the government has given out erroneous

information. For example, suppose that Charles, a bewildered, disabled navy employee, is receiving a

federal disability annuity. Under the regulations, he would lose his pension if he took a job that paid him

in each of two succeeding years more than 80 percent of what he earned in his old navy job. A few years

later, Congress changed the law, making him ineligible if he earned more than 80 percent in anyone year.

For many years, Charles earned considerably less than the ceiling amount. But then one year he got the

opportunity to make some extra money. Not wishing to lose his pension, he called an employee relations

specialist in the US Navy and asked how much he could earn and still keep his pension. The specialist

gave him erroneous information over the telephone and then sent him an out-of-date form that said

Charles could safely take on the extra work. Unfortunately, as it turned out, Charles did exceed the salary

limit, and so the government cut off his pension during the time he earned too much. Charles sues to

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
244

recover his lost pension. He argues that he relied to his detriment on false information supplied by the

navy and that in fairness the government should be estopped from denying his claim.

Unfortunately for Charles, he will lose his case. In Office of Personnel Management v. Richmond, the

Supreme Court reasoned that it would be unconstitutional to permit recovery. [4] The appropriations

clause of Article I says that federal money can be paid out only through an appropriation made by law.

The law prevented this particular payment to be made. If the court were to make an exception, it would

permit executive officials in effect to make binding payments, even though unauthorized, simply by

misrepresenting the facts. The harsh reality, therefore, is that mistakes of the government are generally

held against the individual, not the government, unless the law specifically provides for recompense (as,

for example, in the Federal Tort Claims Act just discussed).

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

After exhausting administrative remedies, there are numerous grounds for seeking

judicial review of an agency’s order or of a final rule. While courts defer to agencies to

some degree, an agency must follow its own rules, comply with the Administrative

Procedure Act, act within the scope of its delegated authority, avoid acting in an

arbitrary manner, and make final rules that are supported by substantial evidence.

E X E R C I S E S

1. Why would US courts require that someone seeking judicial review of an agency

order first exhaust administrative remedies?

2. On the Internet, find a case where someone has successfully sued the US

government under the Federal Tort Claims Act. What kind of case was it? Did the

government argue sovereign immunity? Does sovereign immunity even make sense

to you?

[1] Motor Vehicle Manufacturers’ Assn. v. State Farm Mutual Ins., 463 US 29 (1983).

[2] Dalehite v. United States, 346 US 15 (1953).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
245

[3] Bivens v. Six Unknown Federal Narcotics Agents, 403 US 388 (1971).

[4] Office of Personnel Management v. Richmond, 110 S. Ct. 2465 (1990).

5.6 Cases

Marshall v. Barlow’s, Inc.
Marshall v. Barlow’s, Inc.

436 U.S. 307 (U.S. Supreme Court 1978)

MR. JUSTICE WHITE delivered the opinion of the Court.

Section 8(a) of the Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970 (OSHA or Act) empowers agents of the

Secretary of Labor (Secretary) to search the work area of any employment facility within the Act’s

jurisdiction. The purpose of the search is to inspect for safety hazards and violations of OSHA regulations.

No search warrant or other process is expressly required under the Act.

On the morning of September 11, 1975, an OSHA inspector entered the customer service area of Barlow’s,

Inc., an electrical and plumbing installation business located in Pocatello, Idaho. The president and

general manager, Ferrol G. “Bill” Barlow, was on hand; and the OSHA inspector, after showing his

credentials, informed Mr. Barlow that he wished to conduct a search of the working areas of the business.

Mr. Barlow inquired whether any complaint had been received about his company. The inspector

answered no, but that Barlow’s, Inc., had simply turned up in the agency’s selection process. The inspector

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
246

again asked to enter the nonpublic area of the business; Mr. Barlow’s response was to inquire whether the

inspector had a search warrant.

The inspector had none. Thereupon, Mr. Barlow refused the inspector admission to the employee area of

his business. He said he was relying on his rights as guaranteed by the Fourth Amendment of the United

States Constitution.

Three months later, the Secretary petitioned the United States District Court for the District of Idaho to

issue an order compelling Mr. Barlow to admit the inspector. The requested order was issued on

December 30, 1975, and was presented to Mr. Barlow on January 5, 1976. Mr. Barlow again refused

admission, and he sought his own injunctive relief against the warrantless searches assertedly permitted

by OSHA.…The Warrant Clause of the Fourth Amendment protects commercial buildings as well as

private homes. To hold otherwise would belie the origin of that Amendment, and the American colonial

experience.

An important forerunner of the first 10 Amendments to the United States Constitution, the Virginia Bill of

Rights, specifically opposed “general warrants, whereby an officer or messenger may be commanded to

search suspected places without evidence of a fact committed.” The general warrant was a recurring point

of contention in the Colonies immediately preceding the Revolution. The particular offensiveness it

engendered was acutely felt by the merchants and businessmen whose premises and products were

inspected for compliance with the several parliamentary revenue measures that most irritated the

colonists.…

* * *

This Court has already held that warrantless searches are generally unreasonable, and that this rule

applies to commercial premises as well as homes. In Camara v. Municipal Court, we held:

[E]xcept in certain carefully defined classes of cases, a search of private property without proper consent

is ‘unreasonable’ unless it has been authorized by a valid search warrant.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
247

On the same day, we also ruled: As we explained in Camara, a search of private houses is presumptively

unreasonable if conducted without a warrant. The businessman, like the occupant of a residence, has a

constitutional right to go about his business free from unreasonable official entries upon his private

commercial property. The businessman, too, has that right placed in jeopardy if the decision to enter and

inspect for violation of regulatory laws can be made and enforced by the inspector in the field without

official authority evidenced by a warrant. These same cases also held that the Fourth Amendment

prohibition against unreasonable searches protects against warrantless intrusions during civil as well as

criminal investigations. The reason is found in the “basic purpose of this Amendment…[which] is to

safeguard the privacy and security of individuals against arbitrary invasions by governmental officials.” If

the government intrudes on a person’s property, the privacy interest suffers whether the government’s

motivation is to investigate violations of criminal laws or breaches of other statutory or regulatory

standards.…

[A]n exception from the search warrant requirement has been recognized for “pervasively regulated

business[es],” United States v. Biswell, 406 U.S. 311, 316 (1972), and for “closely regulated” industries

“long subject to close supervision and inspection,” Colonnade Catering Corp. v. United States, 397 U.S.

72, 74, 77 (1970). These cases are indeed exceptions, but they represent responses to relatively unique

circumstances. Certain industries have such a history of government oversight that no reasonable

expectation of privacy could exist for a proprietor over the stock of such an enterprise. Liquor

(Colonnade) and firearms (Biswell) are industries of this type when an entrepreneur embarks upon such a

business, he has voluntarily chosen to subject himself to a full arsenal of governmental regulation.

* * *

The clear import of our cases is that the closely regulated industry of the type involved

in Colonnade and Biswell is the exception. The Secretary would make it the rule. Invoking the Walsh-

Healey Act of 1936, 41 U.S.C. § 35 et seq., the Secretary attempts to support a conclusion that all

businesses involved in interstate commerce have long been subjected to close supervision of employee

safety and health conditions. But…it is quite unconvincing to argue that the imposition of minimum

wages and maximum hours on employers who contracted with the Government under the Walsh-Healey

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
248

Act prepared the entirety of American interstate commerce for regulation of working conditions to the

minutest detail. Nor can any but the most fictional sense of voluntary consent to later searches be found in

the single fact that one conducts a business affecting interstate commerce. Under current practice and

law, few businesses can be conducted without having some effect on interstate commerce.

* * *

The critical fact in this case is that entry over Mr. Barlow’s objection is being sought by a Government

agent. Employees are not being prohibited from reporting OSHA violations. What they observe in their

daily functions is undoubtedly beyond the employer’s reasonable expectation of privacy. The Government

inspector, however, is not an employee. Without a warrant he stands in no better position than a member

of the public. What is observable by the public is observable, without a warrant, by the Government

inspector as well. The owner of a business has not, by the necessary utilization of employees in his

operation, thrown open the areas where employees alone are permitted to the warrantless scrutiny of

Government agents. That an employee is free to report, and the Government is free to use, any evidence of

noncompliance with OSHA that the employee observes furnishes no justification for federal agents to

enter a place of business from which the public is restricted and to conduct their own warrantless search.

* * *

[The District Court judgment is affirmed.]

C A S E Q U E S T I O N S

1. State, as briefly and clearly as possible, the argument that Barlow’s is making

in this case.

2. Why would some industries or businesses be “closely regulated”? What are

some of those businesses?

3. The Fourth Amendment speaks of “people” being secure in their “persons,

houses, papers, and effects.” Why would the Fourth Amendment apply to a

business, which is not in a “house”?

4. If the Fourth Amendment does not distinguish between closely regulated

industries and those that are not, why does the court do so?

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
249

American Textile Manufacturers Institute v. Donovan
American Textile Manufacturers Institute v. Donovan

452 U.S. 490 (1981)

JUSTICE BRENNAN delivered the opinion of the Court.

Congress enacted the Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970 (Act) “to assure so far as possible every

working man and woman in the Nation safe and healthful working conditions.…“The Act authorizes the

Secretary of Labor to establish, after notice and opportunity to comment, mandatory nationwide

standards governing health and safety in the workplace. In 1978, the Secretary, acting through the

Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA), promulgated a standard limiting occupational

exposure to cotton dust, an airborne particle byproduct of the preparation and manufacture of cotton

products, exposure to which produces a “constellation of respiratory effects” known as “byssinosis.” This

disease was one of the expressly recognized health hazards that led to passage of the Act.

Petitioners in these consolidated cases representing the interests of the cotton industry, challenged the

validity of the “Cotton Dust Standard” in the Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit

pursuant to § 6 (f) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. § 655 (f). They contend in this Court, as they did below, that the

Act requires OSHA to demonstrate that its Standard reflects a reasonable relationship between the costs

and benefits associated with the Standard. Respondents, the Secretary of Labor and two labor

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
250

organizations, counter that Congress balanced the costs and benefits in the Act itself, and that the Act

should therefore be construed not to require OSHA to do so. They interpret the Act as mandating that

OSHA enact the most protective standard possible to eliminate a significant risk of material health

impairment, subject to the constraints of economic and technological feasibility.

The Court of Appeals held that the Act did not require OSHA to compare costs and benefits.

We granted certiorari, 449 U.S. 817 (1980), to resolve this important question, which was presented but

not decided in last Term’sIndustrial Union Dept. v. American Petroleum Institute, 448 U.S. 607 (1980),

and to decide other issues related to the Cotton Dust Standard.

* * *

Not until the early 1960’s was byssinosis recognized in the United States as a distinct occupational hazard

associated with cotton mills. In 1966, the American Conference of Governmental Industrial Hygienists

(ACGIH), a private organization, recommended that exposure to total cotton dust be limited to a

“threshold limit value” of 1,000 micrograms per cubic meter of air (1,000 g/m3.) averaged over an 8-hour

workday. See 43 Fed. Reg. 27351, col. 1 (1978). The United States Government first regulated exposure to

cotton dust in 1968, when the Secretary of Labor, pursuant to the Walsh-Healey Act, 41 U.S.C. 35 (e),

promulgated airborne contaminant threshold limit values, applicable to public contractors, that included

the 1,000 g/m3 limit for total cotton dust. 34 Fed. Reg. 7953 (1969). Following passage of the Act in 1970,

the 1,000 g/m3. standard was adopted as an “established Federal standard” under 6 (a) of the Act, 84 Stat.

1593, 29 U.S.C. 655 (a), a provision designed to guarantee immediate protection of workers for the period

between enactment of the statute and promulgation of permanent standards.

That same year, the Director of the National Institute for Occupational Safety and Health (NIOSH),

pursuant to the Act, 29 U.S.C. §§ 669(a)(3), 671 (d)(2), submitted to the Secretary of Labor a

recommendation for a cotton dust standard with a permissible exposure limit (PEL) that “should be set at

the lowest level feasible, but in no case at an environmental concentration as high as 0.2 mg lint-free

cotton dust/cu m,” or 200 g/m3. of lint-free respirable dust. Several months later, OSHA published an

Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 39 Fed.Reg. 44769 (1974), requesting comments from

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
251

interested parties on the NIOSH recommendation and other related matters. Soon thereafter, the Textile

Worker’s Union of America, joined by the North Carolina Public Interest Research Group, petitioned the

Secretary, urging a more stringent PEL of 100 g/m3.

On December 28, 1976, OSHA published a proposal to replace the existing federal standard on cotton dust

with a new permanent standard, pursuant to § 6(b)(5) of the Act, 29 U.S.C. § 655(b)(5). 41 Fed.Reg.

56498. The proposed standard contained a PEL of 200 g/m3of vertical elutriated lint-free respirable

cotton dust for all segments of the cotton industry. Ibid. It also suggested an implementation strategy for

achieving the PEL that relied on respirators for the short term and engineering controls for the long-term.

OSHA invited interested parties to submit written comments within a 90-day period.

* * *

The starting point of our analysis is the language of the statute itself. Section 6(b)(5) of the Act, 29 U.S.C.

§ 655(b)(5) (emphasis added), provides:

The Secretary, in promulgating standards dealing with toxic materials or harmful physical agents under

this subsection, shall set the standard which most adequately assures, to the extent feasible, on the

basis of the best available evidence, that no employee will suffer material impairment of health or

functional capacity even if such employee has regular exposure to the hazard dealt with by such standard

for the period of his working life. Although their interpretations differ, all parties agree that the phrase “to

the extent feasible” contains the critical language in § 6(b)(5) for purposes of these cases.

The plain meaning of the word “feasible” supports respondents’ interpretation of the statute. According to

Webster’s Third New International Dictionary of the English Language 831 (1976), “feasible” means

“capable of being done, executed, or effected.” In accord, the Oxford English Dictionary 116 (1933)

(“Capable of being done, accomplished or carried out”); Funk & Wagnalls New “Standard” Dictionary of

the English Language 903 (1957) (“That may be done, performed or effected”). Thus, § 6(b)(5) directs the

Secretary to issue the standard that “most adequately assures…that no employee will suffer material

impairment of health,” limited only by the extent to which this is “capable of being done.” In effect then,

as the Court of Appeals held, Congress itself defined the basic relationship between costs and benefits, by

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
252

placing the “benefit” of worker health above all other considerations save those making attainment of this

“benefit” unachievable. Any standard based on a balancing of costs and benefits by the Secretary that

strikes a different balance than that struck by Congress would be inconsistent with the command set forth

in § 6(b)(5). Thus, cost-benefit analysis by OSHA is not required by the statute because feasibility analysis

is.

When Congress has intended that an agency engage in cost-benefit analysis, it has clearly indicated such

intent on the face of the statute. One early example is the Flood Control Act of 1936, 33 U.S.C. § 701:

[T]he Federal Government should improve or participate in the improvement of navigable waters or their

tributaries, including watersheds thereof, for flood control purposes if the benefits to whomsoever

they may accrue are in excess of the estimated costs, and if the lives and social security of people

are otherwise adversely affected. (emphasis added)

A more recent example is the Outer Continental Shelf Lands Act Amendments of 1978, providing that

offshore drilling operations shall use the best available and safest technologies which the Secretary

determines to be economically feasible, wherever failure of equipment would have a significant effect on

safety, health, or the environment, except where the Secretary determines that the incremental benefits

are clearly insufficient to justify the incremental costs of using such technologies.

These and other statutes demonstrate that Congress uses specific language when intending that an agency

engage in cost-benefit analysis. Certainly in light of its ordinary meaning, the word “feasible” cannot be

construed to articulate such congressional intent. We therefore reject the argument that Congress

required cost-benefit analysis in § 6(b)(5).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
253

C A S E Q U E S T I O N S

1. What is byssinosis? Why should byssinosis be anything that the textile

companies are responsible for, ethically or legally? If it is well-known that

textile workers get cotton dust in their systems and develop brown lung, don’t

they nevertheless choose to work there and assume the risk of all injuries?

2. By imposing costs on the textile industry, what will be the net effect on US

textile manufacturing jobs?

3. How is byssinosis a “negative externality” that is not paid for by either the

manufacturer or the consumer of textile products? How should the market, to

be fair and efficient, adjust for these negative externalities other than by

setting a reasonable standard that shares the burden between manufacturers

and their employees? Should all the burden be on the manufacturer?

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
254

5.7 Summary and Exercises

Summary
Administrative rules and regulations constitute the largest body of laws that directly affect business.

These regulations are issued by dozens of federal and state agencies that regulate virtually every aspect of

modern business life, including the natural environment, corporate finance, transportation,

telecommunications, energy, labor relations, and trade practices. The administrative agencies derive their

power to promulgate regulations from statutes passed by Congress or state legislatures.

The agencies have a variety of powers. They can license companies to carry on certain activities or prohibit

them from doing so, lay down codes of conduct, set rates that companies may charge for their services,

and supervise various aspects of business.

E X E R C I S E S

1. The Equal Employment Opportunity Commission seeks data about the racial

composition of Terrific Textiles’ labor force. Terrific refuses on the grounds that

inadvertent disclosure of the numbers might cause certain “elements” to picket its

factories. The EEOC takes Terrific to court to get the data. What is the result?

2. In order to police the profession, the state legislature has just passed a law

permitting the State Plumbers’ Association the power to hold hearings to determine

whether a particular plumber has violated the plumbing code of ethics, written by

the association. Sam, a plumber, objects to the convening of a hearing when he is

accused by Roger, a fellow plumber, of acting unethically by soliciting business from

Roger’s customers. Sam goes to court, seeking to enjoin the association’s

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
255

disciplinary committee from holding the hearing. What is the result? How would you

argue Sam’s case? The association’s case?

3. Assume that the new president of the United States was elected overwhelmingly by

pledging in his campaign to “do away with bureaucrats who interfere in your lives.”

The day he takes the oath of office he determines to carry out his pledge. Discuss

which of the following courses he may lawfully follow: (a) Fire all incumbent

commissioners of federal agencies in order to install new appointees. (b) Demand

that all pending regulations being considered by federal agencies be submitted to

the White House for review and redrafting, if necessary. (c) Interview potential

nominees for agency positions to determine whether their regulatory philosophy is

consistent with his.

4. Dewey owned a mine in Wisconsin. He refused to allow Department of Labor agents

into the mine to conduct warrantless searches to determine whether previously

found safety violations had been corrected. The Federal Mine Safety and Health

Amendments Act of 1977 authorizes four warrantless inspections per year. Is the

provision for warrantless inspections by this agency constitutional? [1]

5. In determining the licensing requirements for nuclear reactors, the Nuclear

Regulatory Commission (NRC) adopted a zero-release assumption: that the

permanent storage of certain nuclear waste would have no significant

environmental impact and that potential storage leakages should not be a factor

discussed in the appropriate environmental impact statement (EIS) required before

permitting construction of a nuclear power plant. This assumption is based on the

NRC’s belief that technology would be developed to isolate the wastes from the

environment, and it was clear from the record that the NRC had “digested a massive

material and disclosed all substantial risks” and had considered that the zero-release

assumption was uncertain. There was a remote possibility of contamination by

water leakage into the storage facility. An environmental NGO sued, asserting that

the NRC had violated the regulations governing the EIS by arbitrarily and capriciously

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
256

ignoring the potential contamination. The court of appeals agreed, and the power

plant appealed. Had the NRC acted arbitrarily and capriciously? [2]

S E L F – T E S T Q U E S T I O N S

1. Most federal administrative agencies are created by

a. an executive order by the president

b. a Supreme Court decision

c. the passage of enabling legislation by Congress, signed by the president

d. a and c

The Federal Trade Commission, like most administrative agencies of the federal

government, is part of

a. the executive branch of government

b. the legislative branch of government

c. the judicial branch of government

d. the administrative branch of government

In the Clean Water Act, Congress sets broad guidelines, but it is the

Environmental Protection Agency that proposes rules to regulate industrial

discharges. Where do proposed rules originally appear?

a. in the Congressional record

b. in the Federal Register

c. in the Code of Federal Regulations

d. in the United States code service

The legal basis for all administrative law, including regulations of the Federal

Trade Commission, is found in

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
257

a. the Administrative Procedure Act

b. the US Constitution

c. the commerce clause

d. none of the above

The Federal Trade Commission, like other administrative agencies, has the

power to

a. issue proposed rules

b. undertake investigations of firms that may have violated FTC regulations

c. prosecute firms that have violated FTC regulations

d. none of the above

e. all of the above

S E L F – T E S T A N S W E R S

1. c

2. a

3. b

4. b

5. e

[1] Donovan v. Dewey, 452 US 594 (1981).

[2] Baltimore Gas and Electric Co. v. Natural Resources Defense Council Inc., 462 US 87 (1983).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org

494

Chapter 11

Chapter 11 from Advanced Business Law and the Legal Environment was adapted
by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0

license without attribution as requested by the work’s original creator or licensee. © 2014, The Saylor Foundation.

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/

http://www.saylor.org/site/textbooks/Advanced%20Business%20Law%20and%20the%20Legal%20Environment

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
495

Products Liability

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

After reading this chapter, you should understand the following:

1. How products-liability law allocates the costs of a consumer society

2. How warranty theory works in products liability, and what its limitations are

3. How negligence theory works, and what its problems are

4. How strict liability theory works, and what its limitations are

5. What efforts are made to reform products-liability law, and why

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
496

11.1 Introduction: Why Products-Liability Law Is
Important

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. Understand why products-liability law underwent a revolution in the

twentieth century.

2. Recognize that courts play a vital role in policing the free enterprise system by

adjudicating how the true costs of modern consumer culture are allocated.

3. Know the names of the modern causes of action for products-liability cases.

In previous chapters, we discussed remedies generally. In this chapter, we focus specifically on remedies

available when a defective product causes personal injury or other damages. Products liability describes a

type of claim, not a separate theory of liability. Products liability has strong emotional overtones—ranging

from the prolitigation position of consumer advocates to the conservative perspective of the

manufacturers.

History of Products-Liability Law
The theory of caveat emptor—let the buyer beware—that pretty much governed consumer law from the

early eighteenth century until the early twentieth century made some sense. A horse-drawn buggy is a

fairly simple device: its workings are apparent; a person of average experience in the 1870s would know

whether it was constructed well and made of the proper woods. Most foodstuffs 150 years ago were grown

at home and “put up” in the home kitchen or bought in bulk from a local grocer, subject to inspection and

sampling; people made home remedies for coughs and colds and made many of their own clothes. Houses

and furnishings were built of wood, stone, glass, and plaster—familiar substances. Entertainment was a

book or a piano. The state of technology was such that the things consumed were, for the most part,

comprehensible and—very important—mostly locally made, which meant that the consumer who suffered

damages from a defective product could confront the product’s maker directly. Local reputation is a

powerful influence on behavior.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
497

The free enterprise system confers great benefits, and no one can deny that: materialistically, compare the

image sketched in the previous paragraph with circumstances today. But those benefits come with a cost,

and the fundamental political issue always is who has to pay. Consider the following famous passage from

Upton Sinclair’s great novel The Jungle. It appeared in 1906. He wrote it to inspire labor reform; to his

dismay, the public outrage focused instead on consumer protection reform. Here is his description of the

sausage-making process in a big Chicago meatpacking plant:

There was never the least attention paid to what was cut up for sausage; there would come all the way

back from Europe old sausage that had been rejected, and that was moldy and white—it would be dosed

with borax and glycerin, and dumped into the hoppers, and made over again for home consumption.

There would be meat that had tumbled out on the floor, in the dirt and sawdust, where the workers had

tramped and spit uncounted billions of consumption germs. There would be meat stored in great piles in

rooms; and the water from leaky roofs would drip over it, and thousands of rats would race about on it. It

was too dark in these storage places to see well, but a man could run his hand over these piles of meat and

sweep off handfuls of the dried dung of rats. These rats were nuisances, and the packers would put

poisoned bread out for them; they would die, and then rats, bread, and meat would go into the hoppers

together. This is no fairy story and no joke; the meat would be shoveled into carts, and the man who did

the shoveling would not trouble to lift out a rat even when he saw one—there were things that went into

the sausage in comparison with which a poisoned rat was a tidbit. There was no place for the men to wash

their hands before they ate their dinner, and so they made a practice of washing them in the water that

was to be ladled into the sausage. There were the butt-ends of smoked meat, and the scraps of corned

beef, and all the odds and ends of the waste of the plants, that would be dumped into old barrels in the

cellar and left there.

Under the system of rigid economy which the packers enforced, there were some jobs that it only paid to

do once in a long time, and among these was the cleaning out of the waste barrels. Every spring they did

it; and in the barrels would be dirt and rust and old nails and stale water—and cartload after cartload of it

would be taken up and dumped into the hoppers with fresh meat, and sent out to the public’s breakfast.

Some of it they would make into “smoked” sausage—but as the smoking took time, and was therefore

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
498

expensive, they would call upon their chemistry department, and preserve it with borax and color it with

gelatin to make it brown. All of their sausage came out of the same bowl, but when they came to wrap it

they would stamp some of it “special,” and for this they would charge two cents more a pound. [1]

It became clear from Sinclair’s exposé that associated with the marvels of then-modern meatpacking and

distribution methods was food poisoning: a true cost became apparent. When the true cost of some

money-making enterprise (e.g., cigarettes) becomes inescapably apparent, there are two possibilities.

First, the legislature can in some way mandate that the manufacturer itself pay the cost; with the

meatpacking plants, that would be the imposition of sanitary food-processing standards. Typically,

Congress creates an administrative agency and gives the agency some marching orders, and then the

agency crafts regulations dictating as many industry-wide reform measures as are politically possible.

Second, the people who incur damages from the product (1) suffer and die or (2) access the machinery of

the legal system and sue the manufacturer. If plaintiffs win enough lawsuits, the manufacturer’s insurance

company raises rates, forcing reform (as with high-powered muscle cars in the 1970s); the business goes

bankrupt; or the legislature is pressured to act, either for the consumer or for the manufacturer.

If the industry has enough clout to blunt—by various means—a robust proconsumer legislative response

so that government regulation is too lax to prevent harm, recourse is had through the legal system. Thus

for all the talk about the need for tort reform (discussed later in this chapter), the courts play a vital role in

policing the free enterprise system by adjudicating how the true costs of modern consumer culture are

allocated.

Obviously the situation has improved enormously in a century, but one does not have to look very far to

find terrible problems today. Consider the following, which occurred in 2009–10:

In the United States, Toyota recalled 412,000 passenger cars, mostly the Avalon model, for

steering problems that reportedly led to three accidents.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
499

Portable baby recliners that are supposed to help fussy babies sleep better were recalled after the

death of an infant: the Consumer Product Safety Commission announced the recall of 30,000

Nap Nanny recliners made by Baby Matters of Berwyn, Pennsylvania.

More than 70,000 children and teens go to the emergency room each year for injuries and

complications from medical devices. Contact lenses are the leading culprit, the first detailed

national estimate suggests.

Smith and Noble recalled 1.3 million Roman shades and roller shades after a child was nearly

strangled: the Consumer Product Safety Commission says a five-year-old boy in Tacoma,

Washington, was entangled in the cord of a roller shade in May 2009. [2]

The Consumer Product Safety Commission reported that 4,521 people were killed in the United

States in consumer-product-related incidences in 2009, and millions of people visited hospital

emergency rooms from consumer-product-related injuries. [3]

Reports about the possibility that cell-phone use causes brain cancer continue to be hotly

debated. Critics suggest that the studies minimizing the risk were paid for by cell-phone

manufacturers. [4]

Products liability can also be a life-or-death matter from the manufacturer’s perspective. In 2009,

Bloomberg BusinessWeek reported that the costs of product safety for manufacturing firms can be

enormous: “Peanut Corp., based in Lynchberg, Va., has been driven into bankruptcy since health officials

linked tainted peanuts to more than 600 illnesses and nine deaths. Mattel said the first of several toy

recalls it announced in 2007 cut its quarterly operating income by $30 million. Earlier this decade, Ford

Motor spent roughly $3 billion replacing 10.6 million potentially defective Firestone tires.” [5]Businesses

complain, with good reason, about the expenses associated with products-liability problems.

Current State of the Law
Although the debate has been heated and at times simplistic, the problem of products liability is complex

and most of us regard it with a high degree of ambivalence. We are all consumers, after all, who profit

greatly from living in an industrial society. In this chapter, we examine the legal theories that underlie

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
500

products-liability cases that developed rapidly in the twentieth century to address the problems of

product-caused damages and injuries in an industrial society.

In the typical products-liability case, three legal theories are asserted—a contract theory and two tort

theories. The contract theory is warranty, governed by the UCC, and the two tort theories are

negligence and strict products liability, governed by the common law. See .

Figure 11.1 Major Products Liability Theories

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

As products became increasingly sophisticated and potentially dangerous in the

twentieth century, and as the separation between production and consumption

widened, products liability became a very important issue for both consumers and

manufacturers. Millions of people every year are adversely affected by defective

products, and manufacturers and sellers pay huge amounts for products-liability

insurance and damages. The law has responded with causes of action that provide

a means for recovery for products-liability damages.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
501

E X E R C I S E S

1. How does the separation of production from consumption affect products-

liability issues?

2. What other changes in production and consumption have caused the need for

the development of products-liability law?

3. How can it be said that courts adjudicate the allocation of the costs of a

consumer-oriented economy?

[1] Upton Sinclair, The Jungle (New York: Signet Classic, 1963), 136.

[2] FindLaw, AP reports, http://news.findlaw.com/legalnews/us/pl.

[3] US Consumer Product Safety Commission, 2009 Report to the President and the Congress,

accessed March 1, 2011,http://www.cpsc.gov/cpscpub/pubs/reports/2009rpt .

[4] Matt Hamblen, “New Study Warns of Cell Phone Dangers,”Computerworld US, August 9,

2009, accessed March 1, 2011,http://news.techworld.com/personal-tech/3200539/new-study-

warns-of-cell-phone-dangers.

[5] Michael Orey, “Taking on Toy Safety,” BusinessWeek, March 6, 2009, accessed March 1,

2011,http://www.businessweek.com/managing/content/mar2009/ca2009036_271002.htm.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
502

11.2 Warranties

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. Recognize a UCC express warranty and how it is created.

2. Understand what is meant under the UCC by implied warranties, and know the main

types of implied warranties: merchantability, fitness for a particular purpose, and

title.

3. Know that there are other warranties: against infringement and as may arise from

usage of the trade.

4. See that there are difficulties with warranty theory as a cause of action for products

liability; a federal law has addressed some of these.

The UCC governs express warranties and various implied warranties, and for many years it was the only

statutory control on the use and meanings of warranties. In 1975, after years of debate, Congress passed

and President Gerald Ford signed into law the Magnuson-Moss Act, which imposes certain requirements

on manufacturers and others who warrant their goods. We will examine both the UCC and the Magnuson-

Moss Act.

Types of Warranties
Express Warranties

An express warranty is created whenever the seller affirms that the product will perform in a certain

manner. Formal words such as “warrant” or “guarantee” are not necessary. A seller may create an express

warranty as part of the basis for the bargain of sale by means of (1) an affirmation of a fact or promise

relating to the goods, (2) a description of the goods, or (3) a sample or model. Any of these will create an

express warranty that the goods will conform to the fact, promise, description, sample, or model. Thus a

seller who states that “the use of rustproof linings in the cans would prevent discoloration and

adulteration of the Perform solution” has given an express warranty, whether he realized it or

not. [1] Claims of breach of express warranty are, at base, claims of misrepresentation.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
503

But the courts will not hold a manufacturer to every statement that could conceivably be interpreted to be

an express

warranty.

Manufacturers and sellers constantly “puff” their products, and the law is content to

let them inhabit that gray area without having to make good on every claim. UCC 2-313(2) says that “an

affirmation merely of the value of the goods or a statement purporting to be merely the seller’s opinion or

commendation of the goods does not create a warranty.” Facts do.

It is not always easy, however, to determine the line between an express warranty and a piece of puffery. A

salesperson who says that a strawberry huller is “great” has probably puffed, not warranted, when it turns

out that strawberries run through the huller look like victims of a massacre. But consider the classic cases

of the defective used car and the faulty bull. In the former, the salesperson said the car was in “A-1 shape”

and “mechanically perfect.” In the latter, the seller said not only that the bull calf would “put the buyer on

the map” but that “his father was the greatest living dairy bull.” The car, carrying the buyer’s seven-

month-old child, broke down while the buyer was en route to visit her husband in the army during World

War II. The court said that the salesperson had made an express warranty. [2] The bull calf turned out to be

sterile, putting the farmer on the judicial rather than the dairy map. The court said the seller’s spiel was

trade talk, not a warranty that the bull would impregnate cows. [3]

Is there any qualitative difference between these decisions, other than the quarter century that separates

them and the different courts that rendered them? Perhaps the most that can be said is that the more

specific and measurable the statement’s standards, the more likely it is that a court will hold the seller to a

warranty, and that a written statement is easier to construe as a warranty than an oral one. It is also

possible that courts look, if only subliminally, at how reasonable the buyer was in relying on the

statement, although this ought not to be a strict test. A buyer may be unreasonable in expecting a car to

get 100 miles to the gallon, but if that is what the seller promised, that ought to be an enforceable

warranty.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
504

The CISG (Article 35) provides, “The seller must deliver goods which are of the quantity,

quality and description required by the contract and which are contained or packaged in

the manner required by the contract. [And the] goods must possess the qualities of goods

which the seller has held out to the buyer as a sample or model.”

Implied Warranties

Express warranties are those over which the parties dickered—or could have. Express warranties go to the

essence of the bargain. An implied warranty, by contrast, is one that circumstances alone, not specific

language, compel reading into the sale. In short, an implied warranty is one created by law, acting from an

impulse of common sense.

Implied Warranty of Merchantability

Section 2-314 of the UCC lays down the fundamental rule that goods carry

an implied warranty of merchantability if sold by a merchant-seller. What is merchantability? Section 2-

314(2) of the UCC says that merchantable goods are those that conform at least to the following six

characteristics:

1. Pass without objection in the trade under the contract description

2. In the case of fungible goods, are of fair average quality within the description

3. Are fit for the ordinary purposes for which such goods are used

4. Run, within the variations permitted by the agreement, of even kind, quality, and quantity within

each unit and among all units involved

5. Are adequately contained, packaged, and labeled as the agreement may require

6. Conform to the promise or affirmations of fact made on the container or label if any

For the purposes of Section 2-314(2)(c) of the UCC, selling and serving food or drink for consumption on

or off the premises is a sale subject to the implied warranty of merchantability—the food must be “fit for

the ordinary purposes” to which it is put. The problem is common: you bite into a cherry pit in the cherry-

vanilla ice cream, or you choke on the clam shells in the chowder. Is such food fit for the ordinary

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
505

purposes to which it is put? There are two schools of thought. One asks whether the food was natural as

prepared. This view adopts the seller’s perspective. The other asks what the consumer’s reasonable

expectation was.

The first test is sometimes said to be the “natural-foreign” test. If the substance in the soup is natural to

the substance—as bones are to fish—then the food is fit for consumption. The second test, relying on

reasonable expectations, tends to be the more commonly used test.

The Convention provides (Article 35) that “unless otherwise agreed, the goods sold are fit

for the purposes for which goods of the same description would ordinarily be used.”

Fitness for a Particular Purpose

Section 2-315 of the UCC creates another implied warranty. Whenever a seller, at the time she contracts to

make a sale, knows or has reason to know that the buyer is relying on the seller’s skill or judgment to

select a product that is suitable for the particular purpose the buyer has in mind for the goods to be sold,

there is an implied warranty that the goods are fit for that purpose. For example, you go to a hardware

store and tell the salesclerk that you need a paint that will dry overnight because you are painting your

front door and a rainstorm is predicted for the next day. The clerk gives you a slow-drying oil-based paint

that takes two days to dry. The store has breached an

implied warranty of fitness for particular purpose.

Note the distinction between “particular” and “ordinary” purposes. Paint is made to color and when dry to

protect a surface. That is its ordinary purpose, and had you said only that you wished to buy paint, no

implied warranty of fitness would have been breached. It is only because you had a particular purpose in

mind that the implied warranty arose. Suppose you had found a can of paint in a general store and told

the same tale, but the proprietor had said, “I don’t know enough about that paint to tell you anything

beyond what’s on the label; help yourself.” Not every seller has the requisite degree of skill and knowledge

about every product he sells to give rise to an implied warranty. Ultimately, each case turns on its

particular circumstances:“The Convention provides (Article 35): [The goods must be] fit for

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
506

any particular purpose expressly or impliedly made known to the seller at the time of the

conclusion of the contract, except where the circumstances show that the buyer did not

rely, or that it was unreasonable for him to rely, on the seller’s skill and judgment.”

Other Warranties

Article 2 contains other warranty provisions, though these are not related specifically to products liability.

Thus, under UCC, Section 2-312, unless explicitly excluded, the seller warrants he is conveyinggood

title that is rightfully his and that the goods are transferred free of any security interest or other lien or

encumbrance. In some cases (e.g., a police auction of bicycles picked up around campus and never

claimed), the buyer should know that the seller does not claim title in himself, nor that title will

necessarily be good against a third party, and so subsection (2) excludes warranties in these

circumstances. But the circumstances must be so obvious that no reasonable person would suppose

otherwise.

In Menzel v. List, an art gallery sold a painting by Marc Chagall that it purchased in Paris. [4] The painting

had been stolen by the Germans when the original owner was forced to flee Belgium in the 1930s. Now in

the United States, the original owner discovered that a new owner had the painting and successfully sued

for its return. The customer then sued the gallery, claiming that it had breached the implied warranty of

title when it sold the painting. The court agreed and awarded damages equal to the appreciated value of

the painting. A good-faith purchaser who must surrender stolen goods to their true owner has a claim for

breach of the implied warranty of title against the person from whom he bought the goods.

A second implied warranty, related to title, is that the merchant-seller warrants the goods are free of any

rightful claim by a third personthat the seller has infringed his rights (e.g., that a gallery has not infringed

a copyright by selling a reproduction). This provision only applies to a seller who regularly deals in goods

of the kind in question. If you find an old print in your grandmother’s attic, you do not warrant when you

sell it to a neighbor that it is free of any valid infringement claims.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
507

A third implied warranty in this context involves the course of dealing or usage of trade. Section 2-314(3)

of the UCC says that unless modified or excluded implied warranties may arise from a course of dealing or

usage of trade. If a certain way of doing business is understood, it is not necessary for the seller to state

explicitly that he will abide by the custom; it will be implied. A typical example is the obligation of a dog

dealer to provide pedigree papers to prove the dog’s lineage conforms to the contract.

Problems with Warranty Theory
In General

It may seem that a person asserting a claim for breach of warranty will have a good chance of success

under an express warranty or implied warranty theory of merchantability or fitness for a particular

purpose. In practice, though, claimants are in many cases denied recovery. Here are four general

problems:

The claimant must prove that there was a sale.

The sale was of goods rather than real estate or services.

The action must be brought within the four-year statute of limitations under Article 2-725, when

the tender of delivery is made, not when the plaintiff discovers the defect.

Under UCC, Section 2-607(3)(a) and Section 2A-516(3)(a), which covers leases, the claimant who

fails to give notice of breach within a reasonable time of having accepted the goods will see the

suit dismissed, and few consumers know enough to do so, except when making a complaint about

a purchase of spoiled milk or about paint that wouldn’t dry.

In addition to these general problems, the claimant faces additional difficulties stemming directly from

warranty theory, which we take up later in this chapter.

Exclusion or Modification of Warranties

The UCC permits sellers to exclude or disclaim warranties in whole or in part. That’s reasonable, given

that the discussion here is about contract, and parties are free to make such contracts as they see fit. But a

number of difficulties can arise.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
508

Exclusion of Express Warranties

The simplest way for the seller to exclude express warranties is not to give them. To be sure, Section 2-

316(1) of the UCC forbids courts from giving operation to words in fine print that negate or limit express

warranties if doing so would unreasonably conflict with express warranties stated in the main body of the

contract—as, for example, would a blanket statement that “this contract excludes all warranties express or

implied.” The purpose of the UCC provision is to prevent customers from being surprised by unbargained-

for language.

Exclusion of Implied Warranties in General

Implied warranties can be excluded easily enough also, by describing the product with language such as

“as is” or “with all faults.” Nor is exclusion simply a function of what the seller says. The buyer who has

either examined or refused to examine the goods before entering into the contract may not assert an

implied warranty concerning defects an inspection would have revealed.

The Convention provides a similar rule regarding a buyer’s rights when he has failed to

inspect the goods (Article 35): “The seller is not liable…for any lack of conformity of the

goods if at the time of the conclusion of the contract the buyer knew or could not have been

unaware of such lack of conformity.”

Implied Warranty of Merchantability

Section 2-316(2) of the UCC permits the seller to disclaim or modify the implied warranty of

merchantability, as long as the statement actually mentions “merchantability” and, if it is written, is

“conspicuous.” Note that the disclaimer need not be in writing, and—again—all implied warranties can be

excluded as noted.

Implied Warranty of Fitness

Section 2-316(2) of the UCC permits the seller also to disclaim or modify an implied warranty of fitness.

This disclaimer or modification must be in writing, however, and must be conspicuous. It need not

mention fitness explicitly; general language will do. The following sentence, for example, is sufficient to

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
509

exclude all implied warranties of fitness: “There are no warranties that extend beyond the description on

the face of this contract.”

Here is a standard disclaimer clause found in a Dow Chemical Company agreement: “Seller warrants that

the goods supplied here shall conform to the description stated on the front side hereof, that it will convey

good title, and that such goods shall be delivered free from any lawful security interest, lien, or

encumbrance. SELLER MAKES NO WARRANTY OF MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A

PARTICULAR USE. NOR IS THERE ANY OTHER EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTY.”

Conflict between Express and Implied Warranties

Express and implied warranties and their exclusion or limitation can often conflict. Section 2-317 of the

UCC provides certain rules for deciding which should prevail. In general, all warranties are to be

construed as consistent with each other and as cumulative. When that assumption is unreasonable, the

parties’ intention governs the interpretation, according to the following rules: (a) exact or technical

specifications displace an inconsistent sample or model or general language of description; (b) a sample

from an existing bulk displaces inconsistent general language of description; (c) express warranties

displace inconsistent implied warranties other than an implied warranty of fitness for a particular

purpose. Any inconsistency among warranties must always be resolved in favor of the implied warranty of

fitness for a particular purpose. This doesn’t mean that warranty cannot be limited or excluded altogether.

The parties may do so. But in cases of doubt whether it or some other language applies, the implied

warranty of fitness will have a superior claim.

The Magnuson-Moss Act and Phantom Warranties

After years of debate over extending federal law to regulate warranties, Congress enacted the Magnuson-

Moss Federal Trade Commission Warranty Improvement Act (more commonly referred to as the

Magnuson-Moss Act) and President Ford signed it in 1975. The act was designed to clear up confusing and

misleading warranties, where—as Senator Magnuson put it in introducing the bill—“purchasers of

consumer products discover that their warranty may cover a 25-cent part but not the $100 labor charge or

that there is full coverage on a piano so long as it is shipped at the purchaser’s expense to the

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
510

factory.…There is a growing need to generate consumer understanding by clearly and conspicuously

disclosing the terms and conditions of the warranty and by telling the consumer what to do if his

guaranteed product becomes defective or malfunctions.” The Magnuson-Moss Act only applies to

consumer products (for household and domestic uses); commercial purchasers are presumed to be

knowledgeable enough not to need these protections, to be able to hire lawyers, and to be able to include

the cost of product failures into the prices they charge.

The act has several provisions to meet these consumer concerns; it regulates the content of warranties and

the means of disclosing those contents. The act gives the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) the authority

to promulgate detailed regulations to interpret and enforce it. Under FTC regulations, any written

warranty for a product costing a consumer more than ten dollars must disclose in a single document and

in readily understandable language the following nine items of information:

1. The identity of the persons covered by the warranty, whether it is limited to the original purchaser

or fewer than all who might come to own it during the warranty period.

2. A clear description of the products, parts, characteristics, components, or properties covered, and

where necessary for clarity, a description of what is excluded.

3. A statement of what the warrantor will do if the product fails to conform to the warranty,

including items or services the warranty will pay for and, if necessary for clarity, what it will not

pay for.

4. A statement of when the warranty period starts and when it expires.

5. A step-by-step explanation of what the consumer must do to realize on the warranty, including

the names and addresses of those to whom the product must be brought.

6. Instructions on how the consumer can be availed of any informal dispute resolution mechanism

established by the warranty.

7. Any limitations on the duration of implied warranties—since some states do not permit such

limitations, the warranty must contain a statement that any limitations may not apply to the

particular consumer.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
511

8. Any limitations or exclusions on relief, such as consequential damages—as above, the warranty

must explain that some states do not allow such limitations.

9. The following statement: “This warranty gives you specific legal rights, and you may also have

other rights which vary from state to state.”

In addition to these requirements, the act requires that the warranty be labeled either a full or limited

warranty. A full warranty means (1) the defective product or part will be fixed or replaced for free,

including removal and reinstallation; (2) it will be fixed within a reasonable time; (3) the consumer need

not do anything unreasonable (like shipping the piano to the factory) to get warranty service; (4) the

warranty is good for anyone who owns the product during the period of the warranty; (5) the consumer

gets money back or a new product if the item cannot be fixed within a reasonable number of attempts. But

the full warranty may not cover the whole product: it may cover only the hard drive in the computer, for

example; it must state what parts are included and excluded. A limited warranty is less inclusive. It

may cover only parts, not labor; it may require the consumer to bring the product to the store for service;

it may impose a handling charge; it may cover only the first purchaser. Both full and limited warranties

may exclude consequential

damages.

Disclosure of the warranty provisions prior to sale is required by FTC regulations; this can be done in a

number of ways. The text of the warranty can be attached to the product or placed in close conjunction to

it. It can be maintained in a binder kept in each department or otherwise easily accessible to the

consumer. Either the binders must be in plain sight or signs must be posted to call the prospective buyer’s

attention to them. A notice containing the text of the warranty can be posted, or the warranty itself can be

printed on the product’s package or container.

Phantom warranties are addressed by the Magnuson-Moss Act. As we have seen, the UCC permits the

seller to disclaim implied warranties. This authority often led sellers to give what were called phantom

warranties—that is, the express warranty contained disclaimers of implied warranties, thus leaving the

consumer with fewer rights than if no express warranty had been given at all. In the words of the

legislative report of the act, “The bold print giveth, and the fine print taketh away.” The act abolished

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
512

these phantom warranties by providing that if the seller gives a written warranty, whether express or

implied, he cannot disclaim or modify implied warranties. However, a seller who gives a limited warranty

can limit implied warranties to the duration of the limited warranty, if the duration is reasonable.

A seller’s ability to disclaim implied warranties is also limited by state law in two ways. First, by

amendment to the UCC or by separate legislation, some states prohibit disclaimers whenever consumer

products are sold. [5] Second, the UCC at 2-302 provides that unconscionable contracts or clauses will not

be enforced. UCC 2-719(3) provides that limitation of damages for personal injury in the sale of

“consumer goods is prima facie unconscionable, but limitation of damages where the loss is commercial is

not.” (Unconscionability was discussed in (Reference mayer_1.0-ch12 not found in Book).)

A first problem with warranty theory, then, is that it’s possible to disclaim or limit the warranty. The worst

abuses of manipulative and tricky warranties are eliminated by the Magnuson-Moss Act, but there are

several other reasons that warranty theory is not the panacea for claimants who have suffered damages or

injuries as a result of defective products.

Privity

A second problem with warranty law (after exclusion and modification of warranties) is that of privity.

Privity is the legal term for the direct connection between the seller and buyer, the two contracting parties.

For decades, the doctrine of privity has held that one person can sue another only if they are in privity.

That worked well in the days when most commerce was local and the connection between seller and buyer

was immediate. But in a modern industrial (or postindustrial) economy, the product is transported

through a much larger distribution system, as depicted in Figure 11.2 “Chain of Distribution”. Two

questions arise: (1) Is the manufacturer or wholesaler (as opposed to the retailer) liable to the buyer under

warranty theory? and (2) May the buyer’s family or friends assert warranty rights?

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
513

Figure 11.2 Chain of Distribution

Horizontal Privity

Suppose Carl Consumer buys a new lamp for his family’s living room. The lamp is defective: Carl gets a

serious electrical shock when he turns it on. Certainly Carl would be covered by the implied warranty of

merchantability: he’s in direct privity with the seller. But what if Carl’s spouse Carlene is injured? She

didn’t buy the lamp; is she covered? Or suppose Carl’s friend David, visiting for an afternoon, gets zapped.

Is David covered? This gets to horizontal privity, noncontracting parties who suffer damages from

defective goods, such as nonbuyer users, consumers, and bystanders. Horizontal privity determines to

whose benefit the warranty “flows”—who can sue for its breach. In one of its rare instances of

nonuniformity, the UCC does not dictate the result. It gives the states three choices, labeled in Section 2-

318 as Alternatives A, B, and C.

Alternative A says that a seller’s warranty extends “to any natural person who is in the family or

household of his buyer or who is a guest in his home” provided (1) it is reasonable to expect the person

suffering damages to use, consume, or be affected by the goods and (2) the warranty extends only to

damages for personal injury.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
514

Alternative B “extends to any natural person who may reasonably be expected to use, consume, or be

affected by the goods, and who is injured in person by breach of the warranty.” It is less restrictive than

the first alternative: it extends protection to people beyond those in the buyer’s home. For example, what

if Carl took the lamp to a neighbor’s house to illuminate a poker table: under Alternative B, anybody at the

neighbor’s house who suffered injury would be covered by the warranty. But this alternative does not

extend protection to organizations; “natural person” means a human being.

Alternative C is the same as B except that it applies not only to any “natural person” but “to any person

who is injured by breach of the warranty.” This is the most far-reaching alternative because it provides

redress for damage to property as well as for personal injury, and it extends protection to corporations

and other institutional buyers.

One may incidentally note that having three different alternatives for when third-party nonpurchasers can

sue a seller or manufacturer for breach of warranty gives rise to unintended consequences. First, different

outcomes are produced among jurisdictions, including variations in the common law. Second, the great

purpose of the Uniform Commercial Code in promoting national uniformity is undermined. Third, battles

over choice of law—where to file the lawsuit—are generated.

, Section 2A-216, provides basically the same alternatives as applicable to the leasing of goods.

Vertical Privity

The traditional rule was that remote selling parties were not liable: lack of privity was a defense by the

manufacturer or wholesaler to a suit by a buyer with whom these entities did not themselves contract. The

buyer could recover damages from the retailer but not from the original manufacturer, who after all made

the product and who might be much more financially able to honor the warranty. The UCC takes no

position here, but over the last fifty years the judicial trend has been to abolish

this vertical privity requirement. (See Figure 11.2 “Chain of Distribution”; the entities in the

distribution chain are those in vertical privity to the buyer.) It began in 1958, when the Michigan Supreme

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
515

Court overturned the old theory in an opinion written by Justice John D. Voelker (who also wrote the

novel Anatomy of a Murder, under the pen name Robert Traver). [6]

Contributory Negligence, Comparative Negligence, and Assumption of Risk

After disclaimers and privity issues are resolved, other possible impediments facing the plaintiff in a

products-liability warranty case are issues of assumption of the risk, contributory negligence, and

comparative negligence (discussed in Chapter 7 “Introduction to Tort Law” on torts).

Courts uniformly hold that assumption of risk is a defense for sellers against a claim of breach of

warranty, while there is a split of authority over whether comparative and contributory negligence are

defenses. However, the courts’ use of this terminology is often conflicting and confusing. The ultimate

question is really one of causation: was the seller’s breach of the warranty the cause of the plaintiff’s

damages?

The UCC is not markedly helpful in clearing away the confusion caused by years of discussion of

assumption of risk and contributory negligence. Section 2-715(2)(b) of the UCC says that among the forms

of consequential damage for which recovery can be sought is “injury to person or

property proximately resulting from any breach of warranty” (emphasis added). But “proximately” is a

troublesome word. Indeed, ultimately it is a circular word: it means nothing more than that the defendant

must have been a direct enough cause of the damages that the courts will impose liability. Comment 5 to

this section says, “Where the injury involved follows the use of goods without discovery of the defect

causing the damage, the question of ‘proximate’ turns on whether it was reasonable for the buyer to use

the goods without such inspection as would have revealed the defects. If it was not reasonable for him to

do so, or if he did in fact discover the defect prior to his use, the injury would not proximately result from

the breach of warranty.”

Obviously if a sky diver buys a parachute and then discovers a few holes in it, his family would not likely

prevail in court when they sued to recover for his death because the parachute failed to function after he

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
516

jumped at 5,000 feet. But the general notion that it must have been reasonable for a buyer to use goods

without inspection can make a warranty case difficult to prove.

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

A first basis of recovery in products-liability theory is breach of warranty. There are two

types of warranties: express and implied. Under the implied category are three major

subtypes: the implied warranty of merchantability (only given by merchants), the implied

warranty of fitness for a particular purpose, and the implied warranty of title. There are

a number of problems with the use of warranty theory: there must have been a sale of

the goods; the plaintiff must bring the action within the statute of limitations; and the

plaintiff must notify the seller within a reasonable time. The seller may—within the

constraints of the Magnuson-Moss Act—limit or exclude express warranties or limit or

exclude implied warranties. Privity, or lack of it, between buyer and seller has been

significantly eroded as a limitation in warranty theory, but lack of privity may still affect

the plaintiff’s recovery; the plaintiff’s assumption of the risk in using defective goods

may preclude recovery.

1 . E X E R C I S E S

2. What are the two main types of warranties and the important subtypes?

3. Who can make each type of warranty?

4. What general problems does a plaintiff have in bringing a products-liability warranty

case?

5. What problems are presented concerning exclusion or manipulative express

warranties, and how does the Magnuson-Moss Act address them?

6. How are implied warranties excluded?

7. What is the problem of lack of privity, and how does modern law deal with it?

[1] Rhodes Pharmacal Co. v. Continental Can Co., 219 N.E.2d 726 (Ill. 1976).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
517

[2] Wat Henry Pontiac Co. v. Bradley, 210 P.2d 348 (Okla. 1949).

[3] Frederickson v. Hackney, 198 N.W. 806 (Minn. 1924).

[4] Menzel v. List, 246 N.E.2d 742 (N.Y. 1969).

[5] A number of states have special laws that limit the use of the UCC implied warranty

disclaimer rules in consumer sales. Some of these appear in amendments to the UCC and others

are in separate statutes. The broadest approach is that of the nine states that prohibit the

disclaimer of implied warranties in consumer sales (Massachusetts, Connecticut, Maine,

Vermont, Maryland, the District of Columbia, West Virginia, Kansas, Mississippi, and, with

respect to personal injuries only, Alabama). There is a difference in these states whether the

rules apply to manufacturers as well as retailers.

[6] Spence v. Three Rivers Builders & Masonry Supply, Inc., 90 N.W.2d 873 (Mich. 1958).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
518

11.3 Negligence

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. Recognize how the tort theory of negligence may be of use in products-liability

suits.

2. Understand why negligence is often not a satisfactory cause of action in such

suits: proof of it may be difficult, and there are powerful defenses to claims of

negligence.

Negligence is the second theory raised in the typical products-liability case. It is a tort theory (as

compared to breach of warranty, which is of course a contract theory), and it does have this advantage

over warranty theory: privity is never relevant. A pedestrian is struck in an intersection by a car whose

brakes were defectively manufactured. Under no circumstances would breach of warranty be a useful

cause of action for the pedestrian—there is no privity at all. Negligence is considered in detail in the on

torts; it basically means lack of due care.

Typical Negligence Claims: Design Defects and Inadequate Warnings
Negligence theory in products liability is most useful in two types of cases: defective design and defective

warnings.

Design Defects

Manufacturers can be, and often are, held liable for injuries caused by products that were defectively

designed. The question is whether the designer used reasonable care in designing a product reasonably

safe for its foreseeable use. The concern over reasonableness and standards of care are elements of

negligence theory.

Defective-design cases can pose severe problems for manufacturing and safety engineers. More safety

means more cost. Designs altered to improve safety may impair functionality and make the product less

desirable to consumers. At what point safety comes into reasonable balance with performance, cost, and

desirability (see ) is impossible to forecast accurately, though some factors can be taken into account. For

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
519

example, if other manufacturers are marketing comparable products whose design are intrinsically safer,

the less-safe products are likely to lose a test of reasonableness in court.

Figure 11.3 The Reasonable Design Balance

Warning Defects

We noted that a product may be defective if the manufacturer failed to warn the user of potential dangers.

Whether a warning should have been affixed is often a question of what is reasonably foreseeable, and the

failure to affix a warning will be treated as negligence. The manufacturer of a weed killer with poisonous

ingredients is certainly acting negligently when it fails to warn the consumer that the contents are

potentially lethal.

The law governing the necessity to warn and the adequacy of warnings is complex. What is reasonable

turns on the degree to which a product is likely to be misused and, as the disturbing Laaperi case ()

illustrates, whether the hazard is obvious.

Problems with Negligence Theory
Negligence is an ancient cause of action and, as was discussed in the torts chapter, it carries with it a

number of well-developed defenses. Two categories may be mentioned: common-law defenses and

preemption.

Common-Law Defenses against Negligence
Among the problems confronting a plaintiff with a claim of negligence in products-

liability suits (again, these concepts are discussed in the torts chapter) are the following:

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
520

Proving negligence at all: just because a product is defective does not necessarily

prove the manufacturer breached a duty of care.

Proximate cause: even if there was some negligence, the plaintiff must prove her

damages flowed proximately from that negligence.

Contributory and comparative negligence: the plaintiff’s own actions contributed

to the damages.

Subsequent alteration of the product: generally the manufacturer will not be

liable if the product has been changed.

Misuse or abuse of the product: using a lawn mower to trim a hedge or taking too

much of a drug are examples.

Assumption of the risk: knowingly using the product in a risky way.

Preemption

Preemption (or “pre-emption”) is illustrated by this problem: suppose there is a federal standard

concerning the product, and the defendant manufacturer meets it, but the standard is not really very

protective. (It is not uncommon, of course, for federal standard makers of all types to be significantly

influenced by lobbyists for the industries being regulated by the standards.) Is it enough for the

manufacturer to point to its satisfaction of the standard so that such satisfaction preempts (takes over)

any common-law negligence claim? “We built the machine to federal standards: we can’t be liable. Our

compliance with the federal safety standard is an affirmative defense.”

Preemption is typically raised as a defense in suits about (1) cigarettes, (2) FDA-approved medical devices,

(3) motor-boat propellers, (4) pesticides, and (5) motor vehicles. This is a complex area of law. Questions

inevitably arise as to whether there was federal preemption, express or implied. Sometimes courts find

preemption and the consumer loses; sometimes the courts don’t find preemption and the case goes

forward. According to one lawyer who works in this field, there has been “increasing pressure on both the

regulatory and congressional fronts to preempt state laws.” That is, the usual defendants (manufacturers)

push Congress and the regulatory agencies to state explicitly in the law that the federal standards preempt

and defeat state law. [1]

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
521

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

Negligence is a second possible cause of action for products-liability claimants. A

main advantage is that no issues of privity are relevant, but there are often

problems of proof; there are a number of robust common-law defenses, and

federal preemption is a recurring concern for plaintiffs’ lawyers.

E X E R C I S E S

1. What two types of products-liability cases are most often brought under

negligence?

2. How could it be said that merely because a person suffers injury as the result

of a defective product, proof of negligence is not necessarily made?

3. What is “preemption” and how is it used as a sword to defeat products-

liability plaintiffs?

[1] C. Richard Newsome and Andrew F. Knopf, “Federal Preemption: Products Lawyers

Beware,” Florida Justice Association Journal, July 27, 2007, accessed March 1,

2011, http://www.newsomelaw.com/resources/articles/federal-preemption-products-lawyers-

beware.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
522

11.4 Strict Liability in Tort

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. Know what “strict products liability” means and how it differs from the other two

products-liability theories.

2. Understand the basic requirements to prove strict products liability.

3. See what obstacles to recovery remain with this doctrine.

The warranties grounded in the Uniform Commercial Code (UCC) are often ineffective in assuring

recovery for a plaintiff’s injuries. The notice requirements and the ability of a seller to disclaim the

warranties remain bothersome problems, as does the privity requirement in those states that continue to

adhere to it.

Negligence as a products-liability theory obviates any privity problems, but negligence comes with a

number of familiar defenses and with the problems of preemption.

To overcome the obstacles, judges have gone beyond the commercial statutes and the ancient concepts of

negligence. They have fashioned a tort theory of products liability based on the principle of strict

products liability. One court expressed the rationale for the development of the concept as follows:

“The rule of strict liability for defective products is an example of necessary paternalism judicially shifting

risk of loss by application of tort doctrine because [the UCC] scheme fails to adequately cover the

situation. Judicial paternalism is to loss shifting what garlic is to a stew—sometimes necessary to give full

flavor to statutory law, always distinctly noticeable in its result, overwhelmingly counterproductive if

excessive, and never an end in itself.” [1] Paternalism or not, strict liability has become a very important

legal theory in products-liability cases.

Strict Liability Defined
The formulation of strict liability that most courts use is Section 402A of the Restatement of Torts

(Second), set out here in full:

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
523

(1) One who sells any product in a defective condition unreasonably dangerous to the user or consumer or

to his property is subject to liability for physical harm thereby caused to the ultimate user or consumer, or

to his

property, if

(a) the seller is engaged in the business of selling such a product, and

(b) it is expected to and does reach the user or consumer without substantial change in the condition in

which it is sold.

(2) This rule applies even though

(a) the seller has exercised all possible care in the preparation and sale of his product, and

(b) the user or consumer has not bought the product from or entered into any contractual relation with

the seller.

Section 402A of the Restatement avoids the warranty booby traps. It states a rule of law not governed by

the UCC, so limitations and exclusions in warranties will not apply to a suit based on the Restatement

theory. And the consumer is under no obligation to give notice to the seller within a reasonable time of

any injuries. Privity is not a requirement; the language of the Restatement says it applies to “the user or

consumer,” but courts have readily found that bystanders in various situations are entitled to bring

actions under Restatement, Section 402A. The formulation of strict liability, though, is limited to physical

harm. Many courts have held that a person who suffers economic loss must resort to warranty law.

Strict liability avoids some negligence traps, too. No proof of negligence is required. See .

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
524

Figure 11.4 Major Difference between Warranty and Strict Liability

Section 402A Elements
Product in a Defective Condition

Sales of goods but not sales of services are covered under the Restatement, Section 402A. Furthermore,

the plaintiff will not prevail if the product was safe for normal handling and consumption when sold. A

glass soda bottle that is properly capped is not in a defective condition merely because it can be broken if

the consumer should happen to drop it, making the jagged glass dangerous. Chocolate candy bars are not

defective merely because you can become ill by eating too many of them at once. On the other hand, a

seller would be liable for a product defectively packaged, so that it could explode or deteriorate and

change its chemical composition. A product can also be in a defective condition if there is danger that

could come from an anticipated wrongful use, such as a drug that is safe only when taken in limited doses.

Under those circumstances, failure to place an adequate dosage warning on the container makes the

product defective.

The plaintiff bears the burden of proving that the product is in a defective condition, and this burden can

be difficult to meet. Many products are the result of complex feats of engineering. Expert witnesses are

necessary to prove that the products were defectively manufactured, and these are not always easy to

come by. This difficulty of proof is one reason why many cases raise the failure to warn as the dispositive

issue, since in the right case that issue is far easier to prove. The Anderson case (detailed in the exercises

at the end of this chapter) demonstrates that the plaintiff cannot prevail under strict liability merely

because he was injured. It is not the fact of injury that is dispositive but the defective condition of the

product.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
525

Unreasonably Dangerous

The product must be not merely dangerous but unreasonably dangerous. Most products have

characteristics that make them dangerous in certain circumstances. As the Restatement commentators

note, “Good whiskey is not unreasonably dangerous merely because it will make some people drunk, and

is especially dangerous to alcoholics; but bad whiskey, containing a dangerous amount of fuel oil, is

unreasonably dangerous.…Good butter is not unreasonably dangerous merely because, if such be the case,

it deposits cholesterol in the arteries and leads to heart attacks; but bad butter, contaminated with

poisonous fish oil, is unreasonably dangerous.” [2] Under Section 402A, “the article sold must be

dangerous to an extent beyond that which would be contemplated by the ordinary consumer who

purchases it, with the ordinary knowledge common to the community as to its characteristics. ”

Even high risks of danger are not necessarily unreasonable. Some products are unavoidably unsafe; rabies

vaccines, for example, can cause dreadful side effects. But the disease itself, almost always fatal, is worse.

A product is unavoidably unsafe when it cannot be made safe for its intended purpose given the present

state of human knowledge. Because important benefits may flow from the product’s use, its producer or

seller ought not to be held liable for its danger.

However, the failure to warn a potential user of possible hazards can make a product defective under

Restatement, Section 402A, whether unreasonably dangerous or even unavoidably unsafe. The dairy

farmer need not warn those with common allergies to eggs, because it will be presumed that the person

with an allergic reaction to common foodstuffs will be aware of them. But when the product contains an

ingredient that could cause toxic effects in a substantial number of people and its danger is not widely

known (or if known, is not an ingredient that would commonly be supposed to be in the product), the lack

of a warning could make the product unreasonably dangerous within the meaning of Restatement, Section

402A. Many of the suits brought by asbestos workers charged exactly this point; “The utility of an

insulation product containing asbestos may outweigh the known or foreseeable risk to the insulation

workers and thus justify its marketing. The product could still be unreasonably dangerous, however, if

unaccompanied by adequate warnings. An insulation worker, no less than any other product user, has a

right to decide whether to expose himself to the risk.” [3] This rule of law came to haunt the Manville

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
526

Corporation: it was so burdened with lawsuits, brought and likely to be brought for its sale of asbestos—a

known carcinogen—that it declared bankruptcy in 1982 and shucked its liability. [4]

Engaged in the Business of Selling

Restatement, Section 402A(1)(a), limits liability to sellers “engaged in the business of selling such a

product.” The rule is intended to apply to people and entities engaged in business, not to casual one-time

sellers. The business need not be solely in the defective product; a movie theater that sells popcorn with a

razor blade inside is no less liable than a grocery store that does so. But strict liability under this rule does

not attach to a private individual who sells his own automobile. In this sense, Restatement, Section 402A,

is analogous to the UCC’s limitation of the warranty of merchantability to the merchant.

The requirement that the defendant be in the business of selling gets to the rationale for the whole

concept of strict products liability: businesses should shoulder the cost of injuries because they are in the

best position to spread the risk and distribute the expense among the public. This same policy has been

the rationale for holding bailors and lessors liable for defective equipment just as if they had been

sellers.[5]

Reaches the User without Change in Condition

Restatement, Section 402A(1)(b), limits strict liability to those defective products that are expected to and

do reach the user or consumer without substantial change in the condition in which the products are sold.

A product that is safe when delivered cannot subject the seller to liability if it is subsequently mishandled

or changed. The seller, however, must anticipate in appropriate cases that the product will be stored;

faulty packaging or sterilization may be the grounds for liability if the product deteriorates before being

used.

Liability Despite Exercise of All Due Care

Strict liability applies under the Restatement rule even though “the seller has exercised all possible care in

the preparation and sale of his product.” This is the crux of “strict liability” and distinguishes it from the

conventional theory of negligence. It does not matter how reasonably the seller acted or how exemplary is

a manufacturer’s quality control system—what matters is whether the product was defective and the user

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
527

injured as a result. Suppose an automated bottle factory manufactures 1,000 bottles per hour under

exacting standards, with a rigorous and costly quality-control program designed to weed out any bottles

showing even an infinitesimal amount of stress. The plant is “state of the art,” and its computerized

quality-control operation is the best in the world. It regularly detects the one out of every 10,000 bottles

that analysis has shown will be defective. Despite this intense effort, it proves impossible to weed out

every defective bottle; one out of one million, say, will still escape detection. Assume that a bottle, filled

with soda, finds its way into a consumer’s home, explodes when handled, sends glass shards into his eye,

and blinds him. Under negligence, the bottler has no liability; under strict liability, the bottler will be

liable to the consumer.

Liability without Contractual Relation

Under Restatement, Section 402A(2)(b), strict liability applies even though the user has not purchased

the product from the seller nor has the user entered into any contractual relation with the seller. In short,

privity is abolished and the injured user may use the theory of strict liability against manufacturers and

wholesalers as well as retailers. Here, however, the courts have varied in their approaches; the trend has

been to allow bystanders recovery. The Restatement explicitly leaves open the question of the bystander’s

right to recover under strict

liability.

Problems with Strict Liability
Strict liability is liability without proof of negligence and without privity. It would seem that strict liability

is the “holy grail” of products-liability lawyers: the complete answer. Well, no, it’s not the holy grail. It is

certainly true that 402A abolishes the contractual problems of warranty. Restatement, Section 402A,

Comment m, says,

The rule stated in this Section is not governed by the provisions of the Uniform Commercial Code, as to

warranties; and it is not affected by limitations on the scope and content of warranties, or by limitation to

“buyer” and “seller” in those statutes. Nor is the consumer required to give notice to the seller of his injury

within a reasonable time after it occurs, as provided by the Uniform Act. The consumer’s cause of action

does not depend upon the validity of his contract with the person from whom he acquires the product, and

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
528

it is not affected by any disclaimer or other agreement, whether it be between the seller and his immediate

buyer, or attached to and accompanying the product into the consumer’s hands. In short, “warranty” must

be given a new and different meaning if it is used in connection with this Section. It is much simpler to

regard the liability here stated as merely one of strict liability in tort.

Inherent in the Restatement’s language is the obvious point that if the product has been altered, losses

caused by injury are not the manufacturer’s liability. Beyond that there are still some limitations to strict

liability.

Disclaimers

Comment m specifically says the cause of action under Restatement, Section 402A, is not

affected by disclaimer. But in nonconsumer cases, courts have allowed clear and specific

disclaimers. In 1969, the Ninth Circuit observed: “In Kaiser Steel Corp. the [California Supreme

Court] court upheld the dismissal of a strict liability action when the parties, dealing from

positions of relatively equal economic strength, contracted in a commercial setting to limit the

defendant’s liability. The court went on to hold that in this situation the strict liability cause of

action does not apply at all. In reaching this conclusion, the court inKaiser reasoned that strict

liability ‘is designed to encompass situations in which the principles of sales warranties serve

their purpose “fitfully at best.”’ [Citation]” It concluded that in such commercial settings the

UCC principles work well and “to apply the tort doctrines of products liability will displace the

statutory law rather than bring out its full flavor.” [6]

Plaintiff’s Conduct
Conduct by the plaintiff herself may defeat recovery in two circumstances.

Assumption of Risk

Courts have allowed the defense of assumption of the risk in strict products-liability cases. A plaintiff

assumes the risk of injury, thus establishing defense to claim of strict products liability, when he is aware

the product is defective, knows the defect makes the product unreasonably dangerous, has reasonable

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
529

opportunity to elect whether to expose himself to the danger, and nevertheless proceeds to make use of

the product. The rule makes sense.

Misuse or Abuse of the Product

Where the plaintiff does not know a use of the product is dangerous but nevertheless uses for an incorrect

purpose, a defense arises, but only if such misuse was not foreseeable. If it was, the manufacturer should

warn against that misuse. In Eastman v. Stanley Works, a carpenter used a framing hammer to drive

masonry nails; the claw of the hammer broke off, striking him in the eye. [7] He sued. The court held that

while a defense does exist “where the product is used in a capacity which is unforeseeable by the

manufacturer and completely incompatible with the product’s design…misuse of a product suggests a use

which was unanticipated or unexpected by the product manufacturer, or unforeseeable and unanticipated

[but] it was not the case that reasonable minds could only conclude that appellee misused the [hammer].

Though the plaintiff’s use of the hammer might have been unreasonable, unreasonable use is not a

defense to a strict product-liability action or to a negligence action.”

Limited Remedy

The Restatement says recovery under strict liability is limited to “physical harm thereby caused to the

ultimate user or consumer, or to his property,” but not other losses and not economic losses. In Atlas Air

v. General Electric, a New York court held that the “economic loss rule” (no recovery for economic losses)

barred strict products-liability and negligence claims by the purchaser of a used airplane against the

airplane engine manufacturer for damage to the plane caused by an emergency landing necessitated by

engine failure, where the purchaser merely alleged economic losses with respect to the plane itself, and

not damages for personal injury (recovery for damage to the engine was allowed). [8]

But there are exceptions. In Duffin v. Idaho Crop Imp. Ass’n, the court recognized that a party generally

owes no duty to exercise due care to avoid purely economic loss, but if there is a “special relationship”

between the parties such that it would be equitable to impose such a duty, the duty will be imposed. [9] “In

other words, there is an extremely limited group of cases where the law of negligence extends its

protections to a party’s economic interest.”

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
530

The Third Restatement
The law develops. What seemed fitting in 1964 when the Restatement (Second) announced the state of the

common-law rules for strict liability in Section 402A seemed, by 1997, not to be tracking common law

entirely closely. The American Law Institute came out with the Restatement (Third) in that year. The

Restatement changes some things. Most notably it abolishes the “unreasonably dangerous” test and

substitutes a “risk-utility test.” That is, a product is not defective unless its riskiness outweighs its utility.

More important, the Restatement (Third), Section 2, now requires the plaintiff to provide a reasonable

alternative design to the product in question. In advancing a reasonable alternative design, the plaintiff is

not required to offer a prototype product. The plaintiff must only show that the proposed alternative

design exists and is superior to the product in question. The Restatement (Third) also makes it more

difficult for plaintiffs to sue drug companies successfully. One legal scholar commented as follows on the

Restatement (Third):

The provisions of the Third Restatement, if implemented by the courts, will establish a degree of fairness

in the products liability arena. If courts adopt the Third Restatement’s elimination of the “consumer

expectations test,” this change alone will strip juries of the ability to render decisions based on potentially

subjective, capricious and unscientific opinions that a particular product design is unduly dangerous

based on its performance in a single incident. More important, plaintiffs will be required to propose a

reasonable alternative design to the product in question. Such a requirement will force plaintiffs to prove

that a better product design exists other than in the unproven and untested domain of their experts’

imaginations.[10]

Of course some people put more faith in juries than is evident here. The new Restatement has been

adopted by a few jurisdictions and some cases the adopting jurisdictions incorporate some of its ideas, but

courts appear reluctant to abandon familiar precedent.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
531

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

Because the doctrines of breach of warranty and negligence did not provide adequate

relief to those suffering damages or injuries in products-liability cases, beginning in the

1960s courts developed a new tort theory: strict products liability, restated in the

Second Restatement, section 402A. Basically the doctrine says that if goods sold are

unreasonably dangerous or defective, the merchant-seller will be liable for the

immediate property loss and personal injuries caused thereby. But there remain

obstacles to recovery even under this expanded concept of liability: disclaimers of

liability have not completely been dismissed, the plaintiff’s conduct or changes to the

goods may limit recovery, and—with some exceptions—the remedies available are

limited to personal injury (and damage to the goods themselves); economic loss is not

recoverable. Almost forty years of experience with the Second Restatement’s section on

strict liability has seen changes in the law, and the Third Restatement introduces those,

but it has not been widely accepted yet.

E X E R C I S E S

1. What was perceived to be inadequate about warranty and negligence theories that

necessitated the development of strict liability?

2. Briefly describe the doctrine.

3. What defects in goods render their sellers strictly liable?

4. Who counts as a liable seller?

5. What obstacles does a plaintiff have to overcome here, and what limitations are

there to recovery?

[1] Kaiser Steel Corp. v. Westinghouse Electric Corp., 127 Cal. Rptr. 838 (Cal. 1976).

[2] Restatement (Second) of Contracts, Section 402A(i).

[3] Borel v. Fibreboard Paper Products Corp., 493 F.Zd 1076 (5th Cir. 1973).

[4] In re Johns-Manville Corp., 36 R.R. 727 (So. Dist. N.Y. 1984).

[5] Martin v. Ryder Rental, Inc., 353 A.2d 581 (Del. 1976).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
532

[6] Idaho Power Co. v. Westinghouse Electric Corp., 596 F.2d 924, 9CA (1979).

[7] Eastman v. Stanley Works, 907 N.E.2d 768 (Ohio App. 2009).

[8] Atlas Air v. General Electric, 16 A.D.3d 444 (N.Y.A.D. 2005).

[9] Duffin v. Idaho Crop Imp. Ass’n, 895 P.2d 1195 (Idaho 1995).

[10] Quinlivan Wexler LLP, “The 3rd Restatement of Torts—Shaping the Future of Products

Liability Law,” June 1, 1999, accessed March 1,

2011,http://library.findlaw.com/1999/Jun/1/127691.html.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
533

11.5 Tort Reform

L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S

1. See why tort reform is advocated, why it is opposed, and what interests take

each side.

2. Understand some of the significant state reforms in the last two decades.

3. Know what federal reforms have been instituted.

The Cry for Reform
In 1988, The Conference Board published a study that resulted from a survey of more than 500 chief

executive officers from large and small companies regarding the effects of products liability on their firms.

The study concluded that US companies are less competitive in international business because of these

effects and that products-liability laws must be reformed. The reform effort has been under way ever

since, with varying degrees of alarms and finger-pointing as to who is to blame for the “tort crisis,” if there

even is one. Business and professional groups beat the drums for tort reform as a means to guarantee

“fairness” in the courts as well as spur US economic competitiveness in a global marketplace, while

plaintiffs’ attorneys and consumer advocates claim that businesses simply want to externalize costs by

denying recovery to victims of greed and carelessness.

Each side vilifies the other in very unseemly language: probusiness advocates call consumer-oriented

states “judicial hell-holes” and complain of “well-orchestrated campaign[s] by tort lawyer lobbyists and

allies to undo years of tort reform at the state level,” [1] while pro-plaintiff interests claim that there is

“scant evidence” of any tort abuse.[2] It would be more amusing if it were not so shrill and partisan.

Perhaps the most one can say with any certainty is that peoples’ perception of reality is highly colored by

their self-interest. In any event, there have been reforms (or, as the detractors say, “deforms”).

State Reforms
Prodded by astute lobbying by manufacturing and other business trade associations, state legislatures responded to

the cries of manufacturers about the hardships that the judicial transformation of the products-liability lawsuit

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
534

ostensibly worked on them. Most state legislatures have enacted at least one of some three dozen “reform” proposal

pressed on them over the last two decades. Some of these measures do little more than affirm and clarify case law.

Among the most that have passed in several states are outlined in the next sections.

Statutes of Repose

Perhaps nothing so frightens the manufacturer as the occasional reports of cases involving products that

were fifty or sixty years old or more at the time they injured the plaintiff. Many states have addressed this

problem by enacting the so-called statute of repose. This statute establishes a time period, generally

ranging from six to twelve years; the manufacturer is not liable for injuries caused by the product after

this time has passed.

State-of-the-Art Defense

Several states have enacted laws that prevent advances in technology from being held against the

manufacturer. The fear is that a plaintiff will convince a jury a product was defective because it did not use

technology that was later available. Manufacturers have often failed to adopt new advances in technology

for fear that the change will be held against them in a products-liability suit. These new statutes declare

that a manufacturer has a valid defense if it would have been technologically impossible to have used the

new and safer technology at the time the product was manufactured.

Failure to Warn

Since it is often easier to prove that an injury resulted because the manufacturer failed to warn against a

certain use than it is to prove an injury was caused by a defective design, manufacturers are subjected to a

considerable degree of hindsight. Some of the state statutes limit the degree to which the failure to warn

can be used to connect the product and the injury. For example, the manufacturer has a valid defense if it

would have been impossible to foresee that the consumer might misuse the product in a certain way.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
535

Comparative Fault for Consumer Misuse

Contributory negligence is generally not a defense in a strict liability action, while assumption of risk is. In

states that have enacted so-called comparative fault statutes, the user’s damages are pegged to the

percentage of responsibility for the injury that the defendant bears. Thus if the consumer’s misuse of the

product is assessed as having been 20 percent responsible for the accident (or for the extent of the

injuries), the consumer is entitled to only 80 percent of damages, the amount for which the defendant

manufacturer is responsible.

Criminal Penalties

Not all state reform is favorable to manufacturers. Under the California Corporate Criminal Liability Act,

which took effect twenty years ago, companies and managers must notify a state regulatory agency if they

know that a product they are selling in California has a safety defect, and the same rule applies under

certain federal standards, as Toyota executives were informed by their lawyers following alarms about

sudden acceleration in some Toyota automobiles. Failure to provide notice may result in corporate and

individual criminal liability.

Federal Reform
Piecemeal reform of products-liability law in each state has contributed to the basic lack of uniformity

from state to state, giving it a crazy-quilt effect. In the nineteenth century, this might have made little

difference, but today most manufacturers sell in the national market and are subjected to the varying

requirements of the law in every state. For years there has been talk in and out of Congress of enacting a

federal products-liability law that would include reforms adopted in many states, as discussed earlier. So

far, these efforts have been without much success.

Congressional tort legislation is not the only possible federal action to cope with products-related injuries.

In 1972, Congress created the Consumer Product Safety Commission (CPSC) and gave the commission

broad power to act to prevent unsafe consumer products. The CPSC can issue mandatory safety standards

governing design, construction, contents, performance, packaging, and labeling of more than 10,000

consumer products. It can recall unsafe products, recover costs on behalf of injured consumers, prosecute

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
536

those who violate standards, and require manufacturers to issue warnings on hazardous products. It also

regulates four federal laws previously administered by other departments: the Flammable Fabrics Act, the

Hazardous Substances Act, the Poison Prevention Packaging Act, and the Refrigerator Safety Act. In its

early years, the CPSC issued standards for bicycles, power mowers, television sets, architectural glass,

extension cords, book matches, pool slides, and space heaters. But the list of products is long, and the

CPSC’s record is mixed: it has come under fire for being short on regulation and for taking too long to

promulgate the relatively few safety standards it has issued in a decade.

K E Y T A K E A W A Y

Business advocates claim the American tort system—products-liability law

included—is broken and corrupted by grasping plaintiffs’ lawyers; plaintiffs’

lawyers say businesses are greedy and careless and need to be smacked into

recognition of its responsibilities to be more careful. The debate rages on, decade

after decade. But there have been some reforms at the state level, and at the

federal level the Consumer Product Safety Act sets out standards for safe products

and requires recalls for defective ones. It is regularly castigated for (1) being

officious and meddling or (2) being too timid.

E X E R C I S E S

1. Why is it so difficult to determine if there really is a “tort crisis” in the United

States?

2. What reforms have been made to state tort law?

3. What federal legislation affects consumer safety?

[1] American Tort Reform Association website, accessed March 1, 2011,http://www.atra.org.

[2] http://www.shragerlaw.com/html/legal_rights.html.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
537

11.6 Cases

Implied Warranty of Merchantability and the Requirement of a “Sale”
Sheeskin v. Giant Food, Inc.

318 A.2d 874 (Md. App. 1974)

Davidson, J.

Every Friday for over two years Nathan Seigel, age 73, shopped with his wife at a Giant Food Store. This

complex products liability case is before us because on one of these Fridays, 23 October 1970, Mr. Seigel

was carrying a six-pack carton of Coca-Cola from a display bin at the Giant to a shopping cart when one or

more of the bottles exploded. Mr. Seigel lost his footing, fell to the floor and was injured.

In the Circuit Court for Montgomery County, Mr. Seigel sued both the Giant Food, Inc., and the

Washington Coca-Cola Bottling Company, Inc., for damages resulting from their alleged negligence and

breach of an implied warranty. At the conclusion of the trial Judge Walter H. Moorman directed a verdict

in favor of each defendant.…

In an action based on breach of warranty it is necessary for the plaintiff to show the existence of the

warranty, the fact that the warranty was broken and that the breach of warranty was the proximate cause

of the loss sustained. [UCC] 2-314.…The retailer, Giant Food, Inc., contends that appellant failed to prove

that an implied warranty existed between himself and the retailer because he failed to prove that there

was a sale by the retailer to him or a contract of sale between the two. The retailer maintains that there

was no sale or contract of sale because at the time the bottles exploded Mr. Seigel had not yet paid for

them. We do not agree.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
538

[UCC] 2-314(1) states in pertinent part:

Unless excluded or modified, a warranty that the goods shall be merchantable is implied in a contract

for their sale if the seller is a merchant with respect to goods of that kind. [1] (emphasis added)

Thus, in order for the implied warranties of 2-314 to be applicable there must be a “contract for sale.” In

Maryland it has been recognized that neither a completed ‘sale’ nor a fully executed contract for sale is

required. It is enough that there be in existence an executory contract for sale.…

Here, the plaintiff has the burden of showing the existence of the warranty by establishing that at the time

the bottles exploded there was a contract for their sale existing between himself and the Giant. [Citation]

Mr. Titus, the manager of the Giant, testified that the retailer is a “self-service” store in which “the only

way a customer can buy anything is to select it himself and take it to the checkout counter.” He stated that

there are occasions when a customer may select an item in the store and then change his mind and put the

item back. There was no evidence to show that the retailer ever refused to sell an item to a customer once

it had been selected by him or that the retailer did not consider himself bound to sell an item to the

customer after the item had been selected. Finally, Mr. Titus said that an employee of Giant placed the

six-pack of Coca-Cola selected by Mr. Seigel on the shelf with the purchase price already stamped upon it.

Mr. Seigel testified that he picked up the six-pack with the intent to purchase it.

We think that there is sufficient evidence to show that the retailer’s act of placing the bottles upon the

shelf with the price stamped upon the six-pack in which they were contained manifested an intent to offer

them for sale, the terms of the offer being that it would pass title to the goods when Mr. Seigel presented

them at the check-out counter and paid the stated price in cash. We also think that the evidence is

sufficient to show that Mr. Seigel’s act of taking physical possession of the goods with the intent to

purchase them manifested an intent to accept the offer and a promise to take them to the checkout

counter and pay for them there.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
539

[UCC] 2-206 provides in pertinent part:

(1) Unless otherwise unambiguously indicated by the language or circumstances

(a) An offer to make a contract shall be construed as inviting acceptance in any manner and by any

medium reasonable in the circumstances.…

The Official Comment 1 to this section states:

Any reasonable manner of acceptance is intended to be regarded as available unless the offeror has made

quite clear that it will not be acceptable.

In our view the manner by which acceptance was to be accomplished in the transaction herein involved

was not indicated by either language or circumstances. The seller did not make it clear that acceptance

could not be accomplished by a promise rather than an act. Thus it is equally reasonable under the terms

of this specific offer that acceptance could be accomplished in any of three ways: 1) by the act of delivering

the goods to the check-out counter and paying for them; 2) by the promise to pay for the goods as

evidenced by their physical delivery to the check-out counter; and 3) by the promise to deliver the goods

to the check-out counter and to pay for them there as evidenced by taking physical possession of the goods

by their removal from the shelf.

The fact that customers, having once selected goods with the intent to purchase them, are permitted by

the seller to return them to the shelves does not preclude the possibility that a selection of the goods, as

evidenced by taking physical possession of them, could constitute a reasonable mode of acceptance.

Section 2-106(3) provides:

“Termination” occurs when either party pursuant to a power created by agreement or law puts an end to

the contract otherwise then for its breach. On “termination” all obligations which are still executory on

both sides are discharged but any right based on prior breach or performance survives.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
540

Here the evidence that the retailer permits the customer to “change his mind” indicates only an

agreement between the parties to permit the consumer to end his contract with the retailer irrespective of

a breach of the agreement by the retailer. It does not indicate that an agreement does not exist prior to the

exercise of this option by the consumer.…

Here Mr. Seigel testified that all of the circumstances surrounding his selection of the bottles were

normal; that the carton in which the bottles came was not defective; that in lifting the carton from the

shelf and moving it toward his basket the bottles neither touched nor were touched by anything other than

his hand; that they exploded almost instantaneously after he removed them from the shelf; and that as a

result of the explosion he fell injuring himself. It is obvious that Coca-Cola bottles which would break

under normal handling are not fit for the ordinary use for which they were intended and that the

relinquishment of physical control of such a defective bottle to a consumer constitutes a breach of

warranty. Thus the evidence was sufficient to show that when the bottles left the retailer’s control they did

not conform to the representations of the warranty of merchantability, and that this breach of the

warranty was the cause of the loss sustained.…

[Judgment in favor of Giant Foods is reversed and the case remanded for a new trial. Judgment in favor of

the bottler is affirmed because the plaintiff failed to prove that the bottles were defective when they were

delivered to the retailer.]

C A S E Q U E S T I O N S

1. What warranty did the plaintiff complain was breached here?

2. By displaying the soda pop, the store made an offer to its customers. How did the

court say such offers might be accepted?

3. Why did the court get into the discussion about “termination” of the contract?

4. What is the controlling rule of law applied in this case?

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
541

Strict Liability and Bystanders
Embs v. Pepsi-Cola Bottling Co. of Lexington, Kentucky, Inc.

528 S.W.2d 703 (Ky. 1975)

Jukowsky, J.

On the afternoon of July 25, 1970 plaintiff-appellant entered the self-service retail store operated by the

defendant-appellee, Stamper’s Cash Market, Inc., for the purpose of “buying soft drinks for the kids.” She

went to an upright soft drink cooler, removed five bottles and placed them in a carton. Unnoticed by her, a

carton of Seven-Up was sitting on the floor at the edge of the produce counter about one foot from where

she was standing. As she turned away from the cooler she heard an explosion that sounded “like a

shotgun.” When she looked down she saw a gash in her leg, pop on her leg, green pieces of a bottle on the

floor and the Seven-Up carton in the midst of the debris. She did not kick or otherwise come into contact

with the carton of Seven-Up prior to the explosion. Her son, who was with her, recognized the green

pieces of glass as part of a Seven-Up bottle.

She was immediately taken to the hospital by Mrs. Stamper, a managing agent of the store. Mrs. Stamper

told her that a Seven-Up bottle had exploded and that several bottles had exploded that week. Before

leaving the store Mrs. Stamper instructed one of her children to clean up the mess. Apparently, all of the

physical evidence went out with the trash. The location of the Seven-Up carton immediately before the

explosion was not a place where such items were ordinarily kept.…

When she rested her case, the defendants-appellees moved for a directed verdict in their favor. The trial

court granted the motion on the grounds that the doctrine of strict product liability in tort does not extend

beyond users and consumers and that the evidence was insufficient to permit an inference by a reasonably

prudent man that the bottle was defective or if it was, when it became so.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
542

In [Citation] we adopted the view of strict product liability in tort expressed in Section 402 A of the

American Law Institute’s Restatement of Torts 2d.

402 A. Special Liability of Seller of Product for Physical Harm to
User or Consumer
(1) One who sells any product in a defective condition unreasonably dangerous to the user or to his

property is subject to liability for physical harm thereby caused to the ultimate user or consumer, or to his

property, if
(a) the seller is engaged in the business of selling such a product, and
(b) it is expected to and does reach the user or consumer without substantial change in the condition in

which it was sold.

(2) The rule stated in Subsection (1) applies although

(a) the seller has exercised all possible care in the preparation and sale of his product, and
(b) the user or consumer has not bought the product from or entered into any contractual relation with
the seller.

Comment f on that section makes it abundantly clear that this rule applies to any person engaged in the

business of supplying products for use or consumption, including any manufacturer of such a product and

any wholesale or retail dealer or distributor.

Comment c points out that on whatever theory, the justification for the rule has been said to be that the

seller, by marketing his product for use and consumption, has undertaken and assumed a special

responsibility toward any member of the consuming public who may be injured by it; that the public has

the right to and does expect that reputable sellers will stand behind their goods; that public policy

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
543

demands that the burden of accidental injuries caused by products intended for consumption be placed

upon those who market them, and be treated as a cost of production against which liability insurance can

be obtained; and that the consumer of such products is entitled to the maximum of protection at the

hands of someone, and the proper persons to afford it are those who market the products.

The caveat to the section provides that the Institute expresses no opinion as to whether the rule may not

apply to harm to persons other than users or consumers. Comment on caveat o states the Institute

expresses neither approval nor disapproval of expansion of the rule to permit recovery by casual

bystanders and others who may come in contact with the product, and admits there may be no essential

reason why such plaintiffs should not be brought within the scope of protection afforded, other than they

do not have the same reasons for expecting such protection as the consumer who buys a marketed

product, and that the social pressure which has been largely responsible for the development of the rule

has been a consumer’s pressure, and there is not the same demand for the protection of casual

strangers.…

The caveat articulates the essential point: Once strict liability is accepted, bystander recovery is fait

accompli.

Our expressed public policy will be furthered if we minimize the risk of personal injury and property

damage by charging the costs of injuries against the manufacturer who can procure liability insurance and

distribute its expense among the public as a cost of doing business; and since the risk of harm from

defective products exists for mere bystanders and passersby as well as for the purchaser or user, there is

no substantial reason for protecting one class of persons and not the other. The same policy requires us to

maximize protection for the injured third party and promote the public interest in discouraging the

marketing of products having defects that are a menace to the public by imposing strict liability upon

retailers and wholesalers in the distributive chain responsible for marketing the defective product which

injures the bystander. The imposition of strict liability places no unreasonable burden upon sellers

because they can adjust the cost of insurance protection among themselves in the course of their

continuing business relationship.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
544

We must not shirk from extending the rule to the manufacturer for fear that the retailer or middleman

will be impaled on the sword of liability without regard to fault. Their liability was already established

under Section 402 A of the Restatement of Torts 2d. As a matter of public policy the retailer or

middleman as well as the manufacturer should be liable since the loss for injuries resulting from defective

products should be placed on those members of the marketing chain best able to pay the loss, who can

then distribute such risk among themselves by means of insurance and indemnity agreements.

[Citation]…

The result which we reach does not give the bystander a “free ride.” When products and consumers are

considered in the aggregate, bystanders, as a class, purchase most of the same products to which they are

exposed as bystanders. Thus, as a class, they indirectly subsidize the liability of the manufacturer,

middleman and retailer and in this sense do pay for the insurance policy tied to the product.…

For the sake of clarity we restate the extension of the rule. The protections of Section 402 A of the

Restatement of Torts 2d extend to bystanders whose injury from the defective product is reasonably

foreseeable.…

The judgment is reversed and the cause is remanded to the Clark Circuit Court for further proceedings

consistent herewith.

Stephenson, J. (dissenting):

I respectfully dissent from the majority opinion to the extent that it subjects the seller to liability. Every

rule of law in my mind should have a rational basis. I see none here.

Liability of the seller to the user, or consumer, is based upon warranty. Restatement, Second, Torts s

403A. To extend this liability to injuries suffered by a bystander is to depart from any reasonable basis

and impose liability by judicial fiat upon an otherwise innocent defendant. I do not believe that the

expression in the majority opinion which justifies this rule for the reason that the seller may procure

liability insurance protection is a valid legal basis for imposing liability without fault. I respectfully

dissent.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
545

C A S E Q U E S T I O N S

1. Why didn’t the plaintiff here use warranty as a theory of recovery, as Mr. Seigel did

in the previous case?

2. The court offers a rationale for the doctrine of strict products liability. What is it?

3. Restatement, Section 402A, by its terms extends protection “to the ultimate user or

consumer,” but Mrs. Embs [plaintiff-appellant] was not that. What rationale did the

court give for expanding the protection here?

4. Among the entities in the vertical distribution chain—manufacturer, wholesaler,

retailer—who is liable under this doctrine?

5. What argument did Judge Stephenson have in dissent? Is it a good one?

6. What is the controlling rule of law developed in this case?

Failure to Warn
Laaperi v. Sears, Roebuck & Co., Inc.

787 F.2d 726 C.A.1 (Mass. 1986)

Campbell, J.

In March 1976, plaintiff Albin Laaperi purchased a smoke detector from Sears. The detector,

manufactured by the Pittway Corporation, was designed to be powered by AC (electrical) current. Laaperi

installed the detector himself in one of the two upstairs bedrooms in his home.

Early in the morning of December 27, 1976, a fire broke out in the Laaperi home. The three boys in one of

the upstairs bedrooms were killed in the blaze. Laaperi’s 13-year-old daughter Janet, who was sleeping in

the other upstairs bedroom, received burns over 12 percent of her body and was hospitalized for three

weeks.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
546

The uncontroverted testimony at trial was that the smoke detector did not sound an alarm on the night of

the fire. The cause of the fire was later found to be a short circuit in an electrical cord that was located in a

cedar closet in the boys’ bedroom. The Laaperi home had two separate electrical circuits in the upstairs

bedrooms: one which provided electricity to the outlets and one which powered the lighting fixtures. The

smoke detector had been connected to the outlet circuit, which was the circuit that shorted and cut off.

Because the circuit was shorted, the AC-operated smoke detector received no power on the night of the

fire. Therefore, although the detector itself was in no sense defective (indeed, after the fire the charred

detector was tested and found to be operable), no alarm sounded.

Laaperi brought this diversity action against defendants Sears and Pittway, asserting negligent design,

negligent manufacture, breach of warranty, and negligent failure to warn of inherent dangers. The parties

agreed that the applicable law is that of Massachusetts. Before the claims went to the jury, verdicts were

directed in favor of defendants on all theories of liability other than failure to warn.…

Laaperi’s claim under the failure to warn theory was that he was unaware of the danger that the very short

circuit which might ignite a fire in his home could, at the same time, incapacitate the smoke detector. He

contended that had he been warned of this danger, he would have purchased a battery-powered smoke

detector as a back-up or taken some other precaution, such as wiring the detector to a circuit of its own, in

order better to protect his family in the event of an electrical fire.

The jury returned verdicts in favor of Laaperi in all four actions on the failure to warn claim. The jury

assessed damages in the amount of $350,000 [$1,050,000, or about $3,400,000 in 2010 dollars] each of

the three actions brought on behalf of the deceased sons, and $750,000 [about $2,500,000 in 2010

dollars] in the action brought on behalf of Janet Laaperi. The defendants’ motions for directed verdict and

judgment notwithstanding the verdict were denied, and defendants appealed.

Defendants ask us to declare that the risk that an electrical fire could incapacitate an AC-powered smoke

detector is so obvious that the average consumer would not benefit from a warning. This is not a trivial

argument; in earlier—some might say sounder—days, we might have accepted it.… Our sense of the

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
547

current state of the tort law in Massachusetts and most other jurisdictions, however, leads us to conclude

that, today, the matter before us poses a jury question; that “obviousness” in a situation such as this would

be treated by the Massachusetts courts as presenting a question of fact, not of law. To be sure, it would be

obvious to anyone that an electrical outage would cause this smoke detector to fail. But the average

purchaser might not comprehend the specific danger that a fire-causing electrical problem can

simultaneously knock out the circuit into which a smoke detector is wired, causing the detector to fail at

the very moment it is needed. Thus, while the failure of a detector to function as the result of an electrical

malfunction due, say, to a broken power line or a neighborhood power outage would, we think, be obvious

as a matter of law, the failure that occurred here, being associated with the very risk—fire—for which the

device was purchased, was not, or so a jury could find.…

Finally, defendants contend that the award of $750,000 [$2.5 million in 2010 dollars] in damages to

Janet Laaperi was excessive, and should have been overturned by the district court.…

Janet Laaperi testified that on the night of the fire, she woke up and smelled smoke. She woke her friend

who was sleeping in her room, and they climbed out to the icy roof of the house. Her father grabbed her

from the roof and took her down a ladder. She was taken to the hospital. Although she was in “mild

distress,” she was found to be “alert, awake, [and] cooperative.” Her chest was clear. She was diagnosed as

having first and second degree burns of her right calf, both buttocks and heels, and her left lower back, or

approximately 12 percent of her total body area. She also suffered from a burn of her tracheobronchial

mucosa (i.e., the lining of her airway) due to smoke inhalation, and multiple superficial lacerations on her

right hand.

The jury undoubtedly, and understandably, felt a great deal of sympathy for a young girl who, at the age of

13, lost three brothers in a tragic fire. But by law the jury was only permitted to compensate her for those

damages associated with her own injuries. Her injuries included fright and pain at the time of and after

the fire, a three-week hospital stay, some minor discomfort for several weeks after discharge, and a

permanent scar on her lower back. Plaintiff has pointed to no cases, and we have discovered none, in

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
548

which such a large verdict was sustained for such relatively minor injuries, involving no continuing

disability.

The judgments in favor of Albin Laaperi in his capacity as administrator of the estates of his three sons are

affirmed. In the action on behalf of Janet Laaperi, the verdict of the jury is set aside, the judgment of the

district court vacated, and the cause remanded to that court for a new trial limited to the issue of

damages.
C A S E Q U E S T I O N S

1. The “C.A. 1” under the title of the case means it is a US Court of Appeals case from

the First Circuit in Massachusetts. Why is this case in federal court?

2. Why does the court talk about its “sense of the current state of tort law in

Massachusetts” and how this case “would be treated by the Massachusetts courts,”

as if it were not in the state at all but somehow outside?

3. What rule of law is in play here as to the defendants’ liability?

4. This is a tragic case—three boys died in a house fire. Speaking dispassionately—if

not heartlessly—though, did the fire actually cost Mr. Laaperi, or did he lose $3.4

million (in 2010 dollars) as the result of his sons’ deaths? Does it make sense that he

should become a millionaire as a result? Who ends up paying this amount? (The

lawyers’ fees probably took about half.)

5. Is it likely that smoke-alarm manufactures and sellers changed the instructions as a

result of this case?

[1] Uniform Commercial Code, Section 2-316.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
549

11.7 Summary and Exercises

Summary
Products liability describes a type of claim—for injury caused by a defective product—and not a separate

theory of liability. In the typical case, three legal doctrines may be asserted: (1) warranty, (2) negligence,

and (3) strict liability.

If a seller asserts that a product will perform in a certain manner or has certain characteristics, he has

given an express warranty, and he will be held liable for damages if the warranty is breached—that is, if

the goods do not live up to the warranty. Not every conceivable claim is an express warranty; the courts

permit a certain degree of “puffing.”

An implied warranty is one created by law. Goods sold by a merchant-seller carry an implied warranty of

merchantability, meaning that they must possess certain characteristics, such as being of average quality

for the type described and being fit for the ordinary purposes for which they are intended.

An implied warranty of fitness for a particular purpose is created whenever a seller knows or has reason to

know that the buyer is relying on the seller’s knowledge and skill to select a product for the buyer’s

particular purposes.

Under UCC Article 2, the seller also warrants that he is conveying good title and that the goods are free of

any rightful claim by a third person.

UCC Article 2 permits sellers to exclude or disclaim warranties in whole or in part. Thus a seller may

exclude express warranties. He may also disclaim many implied warranties—for example, by noting that

the sale is “as is.” The Magnuson-Moss Act sets out certain types of information that must be included in

any written warranty. The act requires the manufacturer or seller to label the warranty as either “full” or

“limited” depending on what types of defects are covered and what the customer must do to obtain repair

or replacement. The act also abolishes “phantom warranties.”

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
550

Privity once stood as a bar to recovery in suits brought by those one or more steps removed in the

distribution chain from the party who breached a warranty. But the nearly universal trend in the state

courts has been to abolish privity as a defense.

Because various impediments stand in the way of warranty suits, courts have adopted a tort theory of

strict liability, under which a seller is liable for injuries resulting from the sale of any product in a

defective condition if it is unreasonably dangerous to the user or consumer. Typical issues in strict liability

cases are these: Is the defendant a seller engaged in the business of selling? Was the product sold in a

defective condition? Was it unreasonably dangerous, either on its face or because of a failure to warn? Did

the product reach the consumer in an unchanged condition? Strict liability applies regardless of how

careful the seller was and regardless of his lack of contractual relation with the consumer or user.

Manufacturers can also be held liable for negligence—most often for faulty design of products and

inadequate warnings about the hazards of using the product.

The products-liability revolution prompted many state legislatures to enact certain laws limiting to some

degree the manufacturer’s responsibility for defective products. These laws include statutes of repose and

provide a number of other defenses.’

E X E R C I S E S

1. Ralph’s Hardware updated its accounting system and agreed to purchase a

computer system from a manufacturer, Bits and Bytes (BB). During contract

negotiations, BB’s sales representative promised that the system was “A-1” and

“perfect.” However, the written contract, which the parties later signed, disclaimed

all warranties, express and implied. After installation the computer produced only

random numbers and letters, rather than the desired accounting information. Is BB

liable for breaching an express

warranty? Why?

2. Kate owned a small grocery store. One day John went to the store and purchased a

can of chip dip that was, unknown to Kate or John, adulterated. John became

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
551

seriously ill after eating the dip and sued Kate for damages on the grounds that she

breached an implied warranty of merchantability. Is Kate liable? Why?

3. Carrie visited a neighborhood store to purchase some ham, which a salesperson cut

by machine in the store. The next day she made a ham sandwich. In eating the

sandwich, Carrie bit into a piece of cartilage in the ham. As a result, Carrie lost a

tooth, had to undergo root canal treatments, and must now wear a full-coverage

crown to replace the tooth. Is the store liable for the damage? Why?

4. Clarence, a business executive, decided to hold a garage sale. At the sale, his

neighbor Betty mentioned to Clarence that she was the catcher on her city-league

baseball team and was having trouble catching knuckleball pitches, which required a

special catcher’s mitt. Clarence pulled an old mitt from a pile of items that were on

sale and said, “Here, try this.” Betty purchased the mitt but discovered during her

next game that it didn’t work. Has Clarence breached an express or implied

warranty? Why?

5. Sarah purchased several elegant picture frames to hang in her dorm room. She also

purchased a package of self-sticking hangers. Late one evening, while Sarah was

studying business law in the library, the hangers came loose and her frames came

crashing to the floor. After Sarah returned to her room and discovered the rubble,

she examined the box in which the hangers were packaged and found the following

language: “There are no warranties except for the description on this package and

specifically there is NO IMPLIED WARRANTY OF MERCHANTABILITY.” Assuming the

hangers are not of fair, average, ordinary quality, would the hanger company be

liable for breaching an implied warranty of merchantability? Why?

6. A thirteen-year-old boy received a Golfing Gizmo—a device for training novice

golfers—as a gift from his mother. The label on the shipping carton and the cover of

the instruction booklet urged players to “drive the ball with full power” and further

stated: “COMPLETELY SAFE BALL WILL NOT HIT PLAYER.” But while using the device,

the boy was hit in the eye by the ball. Should lack of privity be a defense to the

manufacturer? The manufacturer argued that the Gizmo was a “completely safe”

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
552

training device only when the ball is hit squarely, and—the defendant argued—

plaintiffs could not reasonably expect the Gizmo to be “completely safe” under all

circumstances, particularly those in which the player hits beneath the ball. What

legal argument is this, and is it valid?

7. A bank repossessed a boat and sold it to Donald. During the negotiations with

Donald, Donald stated that he wanted to use the boat for charter service in Florida.

The bank officers handling the sale made no representations concerning the boat

during negotiations. Donald later discovered that the boat was defective and sued

the bank for breach of warranty. Is the bank liable? Why?

8. Tom Anderson, the produce manager at the Thriftway Market in Pasco, Washington,

removed a box of bananas from the top of a stack of produce. When he reached for

a lug of radishes that had been under the bananas, a six-inch spider—Heteropoda

venatoria, commonly called a banana spider—leaped from some wet burlap onto his

left hand and bit him. Nine months later he died of heart failure. His wife brought an

action against Associated Grocers, parent company of Thriftway Market, on theories

of (1) strict products liability under Restatement, Section 402(a); (2) breach of the

implied warranty of merchantability; and (3) negligence. The trial court ruled against

the plaintiff on all three theories. Was that a correct ruling? Explain.

9. A broken water pipe flooded a switchboard at RCA’s office. The flood tripped the

switchboard circuit breakers and deactivated the air-conditioning system. Three

employees were assigned to fix it: an electrical technician with twelve years on-the-

job training, a licensed electrician, and an electrical engineer with twenty years of

experience who had studied power engineering in college. They switched on one of

the circuit breakers, although the engineer said he knew that one was supposed to

test the operation of a wet switchboard before putting it back into use. There was a

“snap” and everyone ran from the room up the stairs and a “big ball of fire” came

after them up the stairs. The plaintiffs argued that the manufacturer of the circuit

breaker had been negligent in failing to give RCA adequate warnings about the

circuit breakers. How should the court rule, and on what theory should it rule?

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
553

10. Plaintiff’s business was to convert vans to RVs, and for this purpose it had used a 3M

adhesive to laminate carpeting to the van walls. This adhesive, however, failed to

hold the fabric in place in hot weather, so Plaintiff approached Northern Adhesive

Co., a manufacturer of adhesives, to find a better one. Plaintiff told Northern why it

wanted the adhesive, and Northern—Defendant—sent several samples to Plaintiff

to experiment with. Northern told Plaintiff that one of the adhesives, Adhesive

7448, was “a match” for the 3M product that previously failed. Plaintiff tested the

samples in a cool plant and determined that Adhesive 7448 was better than the 3M

product. Defendant had said nothing except that “what they would ship would be

like the sample. It would be the same chemistry.” Plaintiff used the adhesive during

the fall and winter; by spring complaints of delamination came in: Adhesive 7448

failed just as the 3M product had. Over 500 vans had to be repaired. How should the

court rule on Plaintiff’s claims of breach of (1) express warranty, (2) implied

warranty of merchantability, and (3) implied warranty of fitness for a particular

purpose?

S E L F – T E S T Q U E S T I O N S

1. In a products-liability case

a. only tort theories are typically asserted

b. both tort and contract theories are typically asserted

c. strict liability is asserted only when negligence is not asserted

d. breach of warranty is not asserted along with strict liability

An implied warranty of merchantability

a. is created by an express warranty

b. is created by law

c. is impossible for a seller to disclaim

d. can be disclaimed by a seller only if the disclaimer is in writing

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
554

A possible defense to breach of warranty is

a. lack of privity

b. absence of an express warranty

c. disclaimer of implied warranties

d. all of the above

Under the strict liability rule in Restatement, Section 402A, the seller is liable for

all injuries resulting from a product

a. even though all possible care has been exercised

b. regardless of the lack of a contract with the user

c. in both of the above situations

d. in none of the above situations

An individual selling her car could be liable

a. for breaching the implied warranty of merchantability

b. under the strict liability theory

c. for breaching the implied warranty of fitness

d. under two of the above

S E L F – T E S T A N S W E R S

1. b

2. b

3. d

4. c

5. d

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1118

Chapter 24
The Nature and Regulation of Real Estate and

the Environment

LEARNING OBJECTIVES

After reading this chapter, you should understand the following:

1. The various kinds of interests (or “estates”) in real

property

2. The various rights that come with ownership of real property

3. What easements are, how they are created, and how they function

4. How ownership of real property is regulated by tort law, by agreement, and by the

public interest (through eminent domain)

5. The various ways in which environmental laws affect the ownership and use of real

property

Real property is an important part of corporate as well as individual wealth. As a consequence, the role of

the corporate real estate manager has become critically important within the corporation. The real estate

manager must be aware not only of the value of land for purchase and sale but also of proper lease

negotiation, tax policies and assessments, zoning and land development, and environmental laws.

In this chapter and in Chapter 25 “The Transfer of Real Estate by Sale” and Chapter 26 “Landlord and

Tenant Law”, we focus on regulation of land use and the environment (see Figure 24.1 “Chapter

Overview”). We divide our discussion of the nature of real estate into three major categories: (1) estates;

(2) rights that are incidental to the possession and ownership of land—for example, the right to air, water,

and minerals; and (3) easements—the rights in lands of others.

Chapter 24 from Advanced Business Law and the Legal Environment was adapted
by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0

license without attribution as requested by the work’s original creator or licensee. © 2014, The Saylor Foundation.

http://www.saylor.org/site/textbooks/Advanced%20Business%20Law%20and%20the%20Legal%20Environment

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1119

24.1 Estates

LEARNING OBJECTIVE

1. Distinguish between the various kinds of estates, or interests, in real property that

the law recognizes.

In property law, an estate is an interest in real property, ranging from absolute dominion and control to

bare possession. Ordinarily when we think of property, we think of only one kind: absolute ownership.

The owner of a car has the right to drive it where and when she wants, rebuild it, repaint it, and sell it or

scrap it. The notion that the owner might lose her property when a particular event happens is foreign to

our concept of personal property. Not so with real property. You would doubtless think it odd if you were

sold a used car subject to the condition that you not paint it a different color—and that if you did, you

would automatically be stripped of ownership. But land can be sold that way. Land and other real

property can be divided into many categories of interests, as we will see. (Be careful not to confuse the

various types of interests in real property with the forms of ownership, such as joint tenancy. An interest

in real property that amounts to an estate is a measure of the degree to which a thing is owned; the form

of ownership deals with the particular person or persons who own it.)

Figure 24.1 Chapter Overview

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1120

The common law distinguishes estates along two main axes: (1) freeholds versus leaseholds and (2)

present versus future interests. A freehold estate is an interest in land that has an uncertain duration.

The freehold can be outright ownership—called the fee simple absolute—or it can be an interest in the

land for the life of the possessor; in either case, it is impossible to say exactly how long the estate will last.

In the case of one who owns property outright, her estate will last until she sells or transfers it; in the case

of a life estate, it will last until the death of the owner or another specified individual. A

leasehold estate is one whose termination date is usually known. A one-year lease, for example, will

expire precisely at the time stated in the lease agreement.

A present estate is one that is currently owned and enjoyed; a future estate is one that will come into the

owner’s possession upon the occurrence of a particular event. In this chapter, we consider both present

and future freehold interests; leasehold interests we save forChapter 26 “Landlord and Tenant Law”.

Present Estates (Freeholds)
Fee Simple Absolute

The strongest form of ownership is known as thefee simple absolute (or fee simple, or merely fee). This is

what we think of when we say that someone “owns” the land. As one court put it, “The grant of a fee in

land conveys to the grantee complete ownership, immediately and forever, with the right of possession

from boundary to boundary and from the center of the earth to the sky, together with all the lawful uses

thereof.” [1] Although the fee simple may be encumbered by a mortgage (you may borrow money against

the equity in your home) or an easement (you may grant someone the right to walk across your backyard),

the underlying control is in the hands of the owner. Though it was once a complex matter in determining

whether a person had been given a fee simple interest, today the law presumes that the estate being

transferred is a fee simple, unless the conveyance expressly states to the contrary. (In her will, Lady Gaga

grants her five-thousand-acre ranch “to my screen idol, Tilda Swinton.” On the death of Lady Gaga,

Swinton takes ownership of the ranch outright in fee simple absolute.)

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1121

Fee Simple Defeasible

Not every transfer of real property creates a fee simple absolute. Some transfers may limit the estate. Any

transfer specifying that the ownership will terminate upon a particular happening is known as a

fee simple defeasible. Suppose, for example, that Mr. Warbucks conveys a tract of land “to Miss

Florence Nightingale, for the purpose of operating her hospital and for no other purpose. Conveyance to

be good as long as hospital remains on the property.” This grant of land will remain the property of Miss

Nightingale and her heirs as long as she and they maintain a hospital. When they stop doing so, the land

will automatically revert to Mr. Warbucks or his heirs, without their having to do anything to regain title.

Note that the conveyance of land could be perpetual but is not absolute, because it will remain the

property of Miss Nightingale only so long as she observes the conditions in the grant.

Life Estates

An estate measured by the life of a particular person is called a life estate. A conventional life estate is

created privately by the parties themselves. The simplest form is that conveyed by the following words: “to

Scarlett for life.” Scarlett becomes a life tenant; as such, she is the owner of the property and may occupy

it for life or lease it or even sell it, but the new tenant or buyer can acquire only as much as Scarlett has to

give, which is ownership for her life (i.e., all she can sell is a life estate in the land, not a fee simple

absolute). If Scarlett sells the house and dies a month later, the buyer’s interest would terminate. A life

estate may be based on the life of someone other than the life tenant: “to Scarlett for the life of Rhett.”

The life tenant may use the property as though he were the owner in fee simple absolute with this

exception: he may not act so as to diminish the value of the property that will ultimately go to the

remainderman—the person who will become owner when the life estate terminates. The life tenant must

pay the life estate for ordinary upkeep of the property, but the remainderman is responsible for

extraordinary repairs.

Some life estates are created by operation of law and are known as legal life estates. The most common

form is a widow’s interest in the real property of her husband. In about one-third of the states, a woman is

entitled to dower, a right to a percentage (often one-third) of the property of her husband when he dies.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1122

Most of these states give a widower a similar interest in the property of his deceased wife. Dower is an

alternative to whatever is bequeathed in the will; the widow has the right to elect the share stated in the

will or the share available under dower. To prevent the dower right from upsetting the interests of remote

purchasers, the right may be waived on sale by having the spouse sign the deed.

Future Estates
To this point, we have been considering present estates. But people also can have future interests in real

property. Despite the implications of its name, the future interest is owned now but is not available to be

used or enjoyed now. For the most part, future interests may be bought and sold, just as land held in fee

simple absolute may be bought and sold. There are several classes of future interests, but in general there

are two major types: reversion and remainder.

Reversion

A reversion arises whenever the estate transferred has a duration less than that originally owned by the

transferor. A typical example of a simple reversion is that which arises when a life estate is conveyed. The

ownership conveyed is only for the life; when the life tenant dies, the ownership interest reverts to the

grantor. Suppose the grantor has died in the meantime. Who gets the reversion interest? Since the

reversion is a class of property that is owned now, it can be inherited, and the grantor’s heirs would take

the reversion at the subsequent death of the life tenant.

Remainder

The transferor need not keep the reversion interest for himself. He can give that interest to someone else,

in which case it is known as a remainder interest, because the remainder of the property is being

transferred. Suppose the transferor conveys land with these words: “to Scarlett for life and then to Rhett.”

Scarlett has a life estate; the remainder goes to Rhett in fee simple absolute. Rhett is said to have a vested

remainder interest, because on Scarlett’s death, he or his heirs will automatically become owners of the

property. Some remainder interests are contingent—and are therefore known as contingent remainder

interests—on the happening of a certain event: “to my mother for her life, then to my sister if she marries

Harold before my mother dies.” The transferor’s sister will become the owner of the property in fee simple

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1123

only if she marries Harold while her mother is alive; otherwise, the property will revert to the transferor

or his heirs. The number of permutations of reversions and remainders can become quite complex, far

more than we have space to discuss in this text.

KEY TAKEAWAY

An estate is an interest in real property. Estates are of many kinds, but one generic

difference is between ownership estates and possessory estates. Fee simple estates and

life estates are ownership estates, while leasehold interests are possessory. Among

ownership estates, the principal division is between present estates and future estates.

An owner of a future estate has an interest that can be bought and sold and that will

ripen into present possession at the end of a period of time, at the end of the life of

another, or with the happening of some contingent event.

EXERCISES

1. Jessa owns a house and lot on 9th Avenue. She sells the house to the Hartley family,

who wish to have a conveyance from her that says, “to Harriet Hartley for life,

remainder to her son, Alexander Sandridge.” Alexander is married to Chloe, and

they have three children, Carmen, Sarah, and Michael. Who has a future interest,

and who has a present interest? What is the correct legal term for Harriet’s estate?

Does Alexander, Carmen, Sarah, or Michael have any part of the estate at the time

Jessa conveys to Harriet using the stated language?

2. After Harriet dies, Alexander wants to sell the property. Alexander and Chloe’s

children are all eighteen years of age or older. Can he convey the property by his

signature alone? Who else needs to sign?

[1] Magnolia Petroleum Co. v. Thompson, 106 F.2d 217 (8th Cir. 1939).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1124

24.2 Rights Incident to Possession and Ownership of
Real Estate

LEARNING OBJECTIVE

1. Understand that property owners have certain rights in the airspace above

their land, in the minerals beneath their land, and even in water that adjoins

their land.

Rights to Airspace
The traditional rule was stated by Lord Coke: “Whoever owns the soil owns up to the sky.” This traditional

rule remains valid today, but its application can cause problems. A simple example would be a person who

builds an extension to the upper story of his house so that it hangs out over the edge of his property line

and thrusts into the airspace of his neighbor. That would clearly be an encroachment on the neighbor’s

property. But is it trespass when an airplane—or an earth satellite—flies over your backyard? Obviously,

the courts must balance the right to travel against landowners’ rights. In U.S. v. Causby, [1] the Court

determined that flights over private land may constitute a diminution in the property value if they are so

low and so frequent as to be a direct and immediate interference with the enjoyment and use of land.

Rights to the Depths
Lord Coke’s dictum applies to the depths as well as the sky. The owner of the surface has the right to the oil, gas, and

minerals below it, although this right can be severed and sold separately. Perplexing questions may arise in the case of

oil and gas, which can flow under the surface. Some states say that oil and gas can be owned by the owner of the

surface land; others say that they are not owned until actually extracted—although the property owner may sell the

exclusive right to extract them from his land. But states with either rule recognize that oil and gas are capable of being

“captured” by drilling that causes oil or gas from under another plot of land to run toward the drilled hole. Since the

possibility of capture can lead to wasteful drilling practices as everyone nearby rushes to capture the precious

commodities, many states have enacted statutes requiring landowners to share the resources.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1125

Rights to Water
The right to determine how bodies of water will be used depends on basic property rules. Two different

approaches to water use in the United States—eastern and western—have developed over time (seeFigure

24.2 “Water Rights”). Eastern states, where water has historically been more plentiful, have adopted the

so-called riparian rights theory, which itself can take two forms. Riparian refers to land that includes a

part of the bed of a waterway or that borders on a public watercourse. A riparian owner is one who owns

such land. What are the rights of upstream and downstream owners of riparian land regarding use of the

waters? One approach is the “natural flow” doctrine: Each riparian owner is entitled to have the river or

other waterway maintained in its natural state. The upstream owner may use the river for drinking

water

or for washing but may not divert it to irrigate his crops or to operate his mill if doing so would materially

change the amount of the flow or the quality of the water. Virtually all eastern states today are not so

restrictive and rely instead on a “reasonable use” doctrine, which permits the benefit to be derived from

use of the waterway to be weighed against the gravity of the harm. This approach is illustrated in Hoover

v. Crane, (see Section 24.6.1 “Reasonable Use Doctrine”. [2]

Figure 24.2 Water Rights

In contrast to riparian rights doctrines, western states have adopted the prior appropriation doctrine. This

rule looks not to equality of interests but to priority in time: first in time is first in right. The first person

to use the water for a beneficial purpose has a right superior to latecomers. This rule applies even if the

first user takes all the water for his own needs and even if other users are riparian owners. This rule

developed in water-scarce states in which development depended on incentives to use rather than hoard

water. Today, the prior appropriation doctrine has come under criticism because it gives incentives to

those who already have the right to the water to continue to use it profligately, rather than to those who

might develop more efficient means of using it.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1126

KEY TAKEAWAY

Property owners have certain rights in the airspace above their land. They also

have rights in subsurface minerals, which include oil and gas. Those property

owners who have bodies of water adjacent to their land will also have certain

rights to withdraw or impound water for their own use. Regarding US water law,

the reasonable use doctrine in the eastern states is distinctly different from the

prior appropriation doctrine in western states.

EXERCISES

1. Steve Hannaford farms in western Nebraska. The farm has passed to

succeeding generations of Hannafords, who use water from the North Platte

River for irrigation purposes. The headlands of the North Platte are in

Colorado, but use of the water from the North Platte by Nebraskans preceded

use of the water by settlers in Colorado. What theory of water rights governs

Nebraska and Colorado residents? Can the state of Colorado divert and use

water in such a way that less of it reaches western Nebraska and the

Hannaford farm? Why or why not?

2. Jamie Stoner decides to put solar panels on the south face of his roof. Jamie

lives on a block of one- and two-bedroom bungalows in South Miami, Florida.

In 2009, someone purchases the house next door and within two years

decides to add a second and third story. This proposed addition will

significantly decrease the utility of Jamie’s solar array. Does Jamie have any

rights that would limit what his new neighbors can do on their own land?

[1] U.S. v. Causby, 328 U.S. 256 (1946).

[2] Hoover v. Crane, 362 Mich. 36, 106 N.W.2d 563 (1960).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1127

24.3 Easements: Rights in the Lands of Others

LEARNING OBJECTIVES

1. Explain the difference between an easement and a license.

2. Describe the ways in which easements can be created.

Definition
An easement is an interest in land created by agreement that permits one person to make use of

another’s estate. This interest can extend to a profit, the taking of something from the other’s land.

Though the common law once distinguished between an easement and profit, today the distinction has

faded, and profits are treated as a type of easement. An easement must be distinguished from a

mere license, which is permission, revocable at the will of the owner, to make use of the owner’s land. An

easement is an estate; a license is personal to the grantee and is not assignable.

The two main types of easements are affirmative and negative. An affirmative easement gives a landowner

the right to use the land of another (e.g., crossing it or using water from it), while a negative easement,

by contrast, prohibits the landowner from using his land in ways that would affect the holder of the

easement. For example, the builder of a solar home would want to obtain negative easements from

neighbors barring them from building structures on their land that would block sunlight from falling on

the solar home. With the growth of solar energy, some states have begun to provide stronger protection by

enacting laws that regulate one’s ability to interfere with the enjoyment of sunlight. These laws range from

a relatively weak statute in Colorado, which sets forth rules for obtaining easements, to the much stronger

statute in California, which says in effect that the owner of a solar device has a vested right to continue to

receive the sunlight.

Another important distinction is made between easements appurtenant and easements in gross.

An easement appurtenantbenefits the owner of adjacent land. The easement is thus appurtenant to the

holder’s land. The benefited land is called the dominant tenement, and the burdened land—that is, the

land subject to the easement—is called the servient tenement (see Figure 24.3 “Easement

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1128

Appurtenant”). An easement in gross is granted independent of the easement holder’s ownership or

possession of land. It is simply an independent right—for example, the right granted to a local delivery

service to drive its trucks across a private roadway to gain access to homes at the other end.

Figure 24.3 Easement Appurtenant

Unless it is explicitly limited to the grantee, an easement appurtenant “runs with the land.” That is, when

the dominant tenement is sold or otherwise conveyed, the new owner automatically owns the easement. A

commercial easement in gross may be transferred—for instance, easements to construct pipelines,

telegraph and telephone lines, and railroad rights of way. However, most noncommercial easements in

gross are not transferable, being deemed personal to the original owner of the easement. Rochelle sells

her friend Mrs. Nanette—who does not own land adjacent to Rochelle—an easement across her country

farm to operate skimobiles during the winter. The easement is personal to Mrs. Nanette; she could not sell

the easement to anyone else.

Creation
Easements may be created by express agreement, either in deeds or in wills. The owner of the dominant

tenement may buy the easement from the owner of the servient tenement or may reserve the easement for

himself when selling part of his land. But courts will sometimes allow implied easements under certain

circumstances. For instance, if the deed refers to an easement that bounds the premises—without

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1129

describing it in any detail—a court could conclude that an easement was intended to pass with the sale of

the property.

An easement can also be implied from prior use. Suppose a seller of land has two lots, with a driveway

connecting both lots to the street. The only way to gain access to the street from the back lot is to use the

driveway, and the seller has always done so. If the seller now sells the back lot, the buyer can establish an

easement in the driveway through the front lot if the prior use was (1) apparent at the time of sale, (2)

continuous, and (3) reasonably necessary for the enjoyment of the back lot. The rule of implied easements

through prior use operates only when the ownership of the dominant and servient tenements was

originally in the same person.

Use of the Easement
The servient owner may use the easement—remember, it is on or under or above his land—as long as his

use does not interfere with the rights of the easement owner. Suppose you have an easement to walk along

a path in the woods owned by your neighbor and to swim in a private lake that adjoins the woods. At the

time you purchased the easement, your neighbor did not use the lake. Now he proposes to swim in it

himself, and you protest. You would not have a sound case, because his swimming in the lake would not

interfere with your right to do so. But if he proposed to clear the woods and build a mill on it, obliterating

the path you took to the lake and polluting the lake with chemical discharges, then you could obtain an

injunction to bar him from interfering with your easement.

The owner of the dominant tenement is not restricted to using his land as he was at the time he became

the owner of the easement. The courts will permit him to develop the land in some “normal” manner. For

example, an easement on a private roadway for the benefit of a large estate up in the hills would not be

lost if the large estate were ultimately subdivided and many new owners wished to use the roadway; the

easement applies to the entire portion of the original dominant tenement, not merely to the part that

abuts the easement itself. However, the owner of an easement appurtenant to one tract of land cannot use

the easement on another tract of land, even if the two tracts are adjacent.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1130

KEY TAKEAWAY

An easement appurtenant runs with the land and benefits the dominant

tenement, burdening the servient tenement. An easement, generally, has a

specific location or description within or over the servient tenement. Easements

can be created by deed, by will, or by implication.
EXERCISE

1. Beth Delaney owns property next to Kerry Plemmons. The deed to Delaney’s

property notes that she has access to a well on the Plemmons property “to

obtain water for household use.” The well has been dry for many generations

and has not been used by anyone on the Plemmons property or the Delaney

property for as many generations. The well predated Plemmons’s ownership

of the property; as the servient tenement, the Plemmons property was

burdened by this easement dating back to 1898. Plemmons hires a company

to dig a very deep well near one of his outbuildings to provide water for his

horses. The location is one hundred yards from the old well. Does the Delaney

property have any easement to use water from the new well?

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1131

24.4 Regulation of Land Use

LEARNING OBJECTIVES

1. Compare the various ways in which law limits or restricts the right to use your

land in any way that you decide is best for you.

2. Distinguish between regulation by common law and regulation by public acts

such as zoning or eminent domain.

3. Understand that property owners may restrict the uses of land by voluntary

agreement, subject to important public policy considerations.

Land use regulation falls into three broad categories: (1) restriction on the use of land through tort law,

(2) private regulation by agreement, and (3) public ownership or regulation through the powers of

eminent domain and zoning.

Regulation of Land Use by Tort Law
Tort law is used to regulate land use in two ways: (1) The owner may become liable for certain activities

carried out on the real estate that affect others beyond the real estate. (2) The owner may be liable to

persons who, upon entering the real estate, are injured.

Landowner’s Activities

The two most common torts in this area are nuisance and trespass. A common-law nuisance is an

interference with the use and enjoyment of one’s land. Examples of nuisances are excessive noise

(especially late at night), polluting activities, and emissions of noxious odors. But the activity must

produce substantial harm, not fleeting, minor injury, and it must produce those effects on the reasonable

person, not on someone who is peculiarly allergic to the complained-of activity. A person who suffered

migraine headaches at the sight of croquet being played on a neighbor’s lawn would not likely win a

nuisance lawsuit. While the meaning of nuisance is difficult to define with any precision, this common-

law cause of action is a primary means for landowners to obtain damages for invasive environmental

harms.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1132

A trespass is the wrongful physical invasion of or entry upon land possessed by another. Loud noise

blaring out of speakers in the house next door might be a nuisance but could not be a trespass, because

noise is not a physical invasion. But spraying pesticides on your gladiolas could constitute a trespass on

your neighbor’s property if the pesticide drifts across the boundary.

Nuisance and trespass are complex theories, a full explanation of which would consume far more space

than we have. What is important to remember is that these torts are two-edged swords. In some

situations, the landowner himself will want to use these theories to sue trespassers or persons creating a

nuisance, but in other situations, the landowner will be liable under these theories for his own activities.

Injury to Persons Entering the Real Estate

Traditionally, liability for injury has depended on the status of the person who enters the real estate.

Trespassers

If the person is an intruder without permission—a trespasser—the landowner owes him no duty of care

unless he knows of the intruder’s presence, in which case the owner must exercise reasonable care in his

activities and warn of hidden dangers on his land of which he is aware. A known trespasser is someone

whom the landowner actually sees on the property or whom he knows frequently intrudes on the

property, as in the case of someone who habitually walks across the land. If a landowner knows that

people frequently walk across his property and one day he puts a poisonous chemical on the ground to

eliminate certain insects, he is obligated to warn those who continue to walk on the grounds. Intentional

injury to known trespassers is not allowed, even if the trespasser is a criminal intent on robbery, for the

law values human life above property rights.

Children

If the trespasser is a child, a different rule applies in most states. This is the doctrine

of attractive nuisance. Originally this rule was enunciated to deal with cases in which something on the

land attracted the child to it, like a swimming pool. In recent years, most courts have dropped the

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1133

requirement that the child must have been attracted to the danger. Instead, the following elements of

proof are necessary to make out a case of attractive nuisance (Restatement of Torts, Section 339):

1. The child must have been injured by a structure or other artificial condition.

2. The possessor of the land (not necessarily the owner) must have known or should have known

that young children would be likely to trespass.

3. The possessor must have known or should have known that the artificial condition exists and that

it posed an unreasonable risk of serious injury.

4. The child must have been too young to appreciate the danger that the artificial condition posed.

5. The risk to the child must have far outweighed the utility of the artificial condition to the

possessor.

6. The possessor did not exercise reasonable care in protecting the child or eliminating the danger.

Old refrigerators, open gravel pits, or mechanisms that a curious child would find inviting are all

examples of attractive nuisance. Suppose Farmer Brown keeps an old buggy on his front lawn, accessible

from the street. A five-year-old boy clambers up the buggy one day, falls through a rotted floorboard, and

breaks his leg. Is Farmer Brown liable? Probably so. The child was too young to appreciate the danger

posed by the buggy, a structure. The farmer should have appreciated that young children would be likely

to come onto the land when they saw the buggy and that they would be likely to climb up onto the buggy.

Moreover, he should have known, if he did not know in fact, that the buggy, left outside for years without

being tended, would pose an unreasonable risk. The buggy’s utility as a decoration was far overbalanced

by the risk that it posed to children, and the farmer failed to exercise reasonable care.

Licensees

A nontrespasser who comes onto the land without being invited, or if invited, comes for purposes

unconnected with any business conducted on the premises, is known as a licensee. This class of visitors

to the land consists of (1) social guests (people you invite to your home for a party); (2) a salesman, not

invited by the owner, who wishes to sell something to the owner or occupier of the property; and (3)

persons visiting a building for a purpose not connected with the business on the land (e.g., students who

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1134

visit a factory to see how it works). The landowner owes the same duty of care to licensees that he owes to

known trespassers. That is, he must warn them against hidden dangers of which he is aware, and he must

exercise reasonable care in his activities to ensure that they are not injured.

Invitees

A final category of persons entering land is that of invitee. This is one who has been invited onto the

land, usually, though not necessarily, for a business purpose of potential economic benefit to the owner or

occupier of the premises. This category is confusing because it sounds as though it should include social

guests (who clearly are invited onto the premises), but traditionally social guests are said to be licensees.

Invitees include customers of stores, users of athletic and other clubs, customers of repair shops, strollers

through public parks, restaurant and theater patrons, hotel guests, and the like. From the owner’s

perspective, the major difference between licensees and invitees is that he is liable for injuries resulting to

the latter from hidden dangers that he should have been aware of, even if he is not actually aware of the

dangers. How hidden the dangers are and how broad the owner’s liability is depends on the

circumstances, but liability sometimes can be quite broad. Difficult questions arise in lawsuits brought by

invitees (or business invitees, as they are sometimes called) when the actions of persons other than the

landowner contribute to the injury.

The foregoing rules dealing with liability for persons entering the land are the traditional rules at common

law. In recent years, some courts have moved away from the rigidities and sometimes perplexing

differences between trespassers, licensees, and invitees. By court decision, several states have now

abolished such distinctions and hold the proprietor, owner, or occupier liable for failing to maintain the

premises in a reasonably safe condition. According to the California Supreme Court,

A man’s life or limb does not become less worthy of protection by the law nor a loss less worthy of

compensation under the law because he has come upon the land of another without permission or with

permission but without a business purpose. Reasonable people do not ordinarily vary their conduct

depending upon such matters, and to focus upon the status of the injured party as a trespasser, licensee,

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1135

or invitee in order to determine the question whether the landowner has a duty of care, is contrary to our

modern social mores and humanitarian values. Where the occupier of land is aware of a concealed

condition involving in the absence of precautions an unreasonable risk of harm to those coming in contact

with it and is aware that a person on the premises is about to come in contact with it, the trier of fact can

reasonably conclude that a failure to warn or to repair the condition constitutes negligence. Whether or

not a guest has a right to expect that his host will remedy dangerous conditions on his account, he should

reasonably be entitled to rely upon a warning of the dangerous condition so that he, like the host, will be

in a position to take special precautions when he comes in contact with it. [1]

Private Regulation of Land Use by Agreement
A restrictive covenant is an agreement regarding the use of land that “runs with the land.” In effect, it is a

contractual promise that becomes part of the property and that binds future owners. Violations of

covenants can be redressed in court in suits for damages or injunctions but will not result in reversion of

the land to the seller.

Usually, courts construe restrictive covenants narrowly—that is, in a manner most conducive to free use of

the land by the ultimate owner (the person against whom enforcement of the covenant is being sought).

Sometimes, even when the meaning of the covenant is clear, the courts will not enforce it. For example,

when the character of a neighborhood changes, the courts may declare the covenant a nullity. Thus a

restriction on a one-acre parcel to residential purposes was voided when in the intervening thirty years a

host of businesses grew up around it, including a bowling alley, restaurant, poolroom, and sewage

disposal plant. [2]

An important nullification of restrictive covenants came in 1947 when the US Supreme Court struck down

as unconstitutional racially restrictive covenants, which barred blacks and other minorities from living on

land so burdened. The Supreme Court reasoned that when a court enforces such a covenant, it acts in a

discriminatory manner (barring blacks but not whites from living in a home burdened with the covenant)

and thus violates the Fourteenth Amendment’s guarantee of equal protection of the laws. [3]

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1136

Public Control of Land Use through Eminent Domain
The government may take private property for public purposes. Its power to do so is known as eminent

domain. The power of eminent domain is subject to constitutional limitations. entitled to “just

compensation” for his loss. These requirements are sometimes difficult to apply.Under the Fifth

Amendment, the property must be put to public use, and the owner is

Public Use

The requirement of public use normally means that the property will be useful to the public once the state

has taken possession—for example, private property might be condemned to construct a highway.

Although not allowed in most circumstances, the government could even condemn someone’s property in

order to turn around and sell it to another individual, if a legitimate public purpose could be shown. For

example, a state survey in the mid-1960s showed that the government owned 49 percent of Hawaii’s land.

Another 47 percent was controlled by seventy-two private landowners. Because this concentration of land

ownership (which dated back to feudal times) resulted in a critical shortage of residential land, the

Hawaiian legislature enacted a law allowing the government to take land from large private estates and

resell it in smaller parcels to homeowners. In 1984, the US Supreme Court upheld the law, deciding that

the land was being taken for a public use because the purpose was “to attack certain perceived evils of

concentrated property ownership.” [4] Although the use must be public, the courts will not inquire into the

necessity of the use or whether other property might have been better suited. It is up to government

authorities to determine whether and where to build a road, not the courts.

The limits of public use were amply illustrated in the Supreme Court’s 2002 decision of Kelo v. New

London, [5] in which Mrs. Kelo’s house was condemned so that the city of New London, in Connecticut,

could create a marina and industrial park to lease to Pfizer Corporation. The city’s motives were to create

a higher tax base for property taxes. The Court, following precedent in Midkiff and other cases, refused to

invalidate the city’s taking on constitutional grounds. Reaction from states was swift; many states passed

new laws restricting the bases for state and municipal governments to use powers of eminent domain, and

many of these laws also provided additional compensation to property owners whose land was taken.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1137

Just Compensation

The owner is ordinarily entitled to the fair market value of land condemned under eminent domain. This

value is determined by calculating the most profitable use of the land at the time of the taking, even

though it was being put to a different use. The owner will have a difficult time collecting lost profits; for

instance, a grocery store will not usually be entitled to collect for the profits it might have made during the

next several years, in part because it can presumably move elsewhere and continue to make profits and in

part because calculating future profits is inherently speculative.

Taking

The most difficult question in most modern cases is whether the government has in fact “taken” the

property. This is easy to answer when the government acquires title to the property through

condemnation proceedings. But more often, a government action is challenged when a law or regulation

inhibits the use of private land. Suppose a town promulgates a setback ordinance, requiring owners along

city sidewalks to build no closer to the sidewalk than twenty feet. If the owner of a small store had only

twenty-five feet of land from the sidewalk line, the ordinance would effectively prevent him from housing

his enterprise, and the ordinance would be a taking. Challenging such ordinances can sometimes be

difficult under traditional tort theories because the government is immune from suit in some of these

cases. Instead, a theory of inverse condemnation has developed, in which the plaintiff private property

owner asserts that the government has condemned the property, though not through the traditional

mechanism of a condemnation proceeding.

Public Control of Land Use through Zoning
Zoning is a technique by which a city or other municipality regulates the type of activity to be permitted

in geographical areas within its boundaries. Though originally limited to residential, commercial, and

industrial uses, today’s zoning ordinances are complex sets of regulations. A typical municipality might

have the following zones: residential with a host of subcategories (such as for single-family and multiple-

family dwellings), office, commercial, industrial, agricultural, and public lands. Zones may be exclusive, in

which case office buildings would not be permitted in commercial zones, or they may be cumulative, so

that a more restricted use would be allowed in a less restrictive zone. Zoning regulations do more than

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1138

specify the type of use: they often also dictate minimum requirements for parking, open usable space,

setbacks, lot sizes, and the like, and maximum requirements for height, length of side lots, and so on.

Nonconforming Uses

When a zoning ordinance is enacted, it will almost always affect existing property owners, many of whom

will be using their land in ways no longer permitted under the ordinance. To avoid the charge that they

have thereby “taken” the property, most ordinances permit previous nonconforming uses to continue,

though some ordinances limit the nonconforming uses to a specified time after becoming effective. But

this permission to continue a nonconforming use is narrow; it extends only to the specific use to which the

property was put before the ordinance was enacted. A manufacturer of dresses that suddenly finds itself in

an area zoned residential may continue to use its sewing machines, but it could not develop a sideline in

woodworking.

Variances

Sometimes an owner may desire to use his property in ways not permitted under an existing zoning

scheme and will ask the zoning board for a variance—authority to carry on a nonconforming use. The

board is not free to grant a variance at its whim. The courts apply three general tests to determine the

validity of a variance: (1) The land must be unable to yield a reasonable return on the uses allowed by the

zoning regulation. (2) The hardship must be unique to the property, not to property generally in the area.

(3) If granted, the variance must not change the essential character of the neighborhood.

KEY TAKEAWAY

Land use regulation can mean (1) restrictions on the use of land through tort law,

(2) private regulation—by agreement, or (3) regulation through powers of eminent

domain or zoning.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1139

EXERCISES

1. Give one example of the exercise of eminent domain. In order to exercise its

power under eminent domain, must the government actually take eventual

ownership of the property that is “taken”?

2. Felix Unger is an adult, trespassing for the first time on Alan Spillborghs’s

property. Alan has been digging a deep grave in his backyard for his beloved

Saint Bernard, Maximilian, who has just died. Alan stops working on the grave

when it gets dark, intending to return to the task in the morning. He seldom

sees trespassers cutting through his backyard. Felix, in the dark, after visiting

the local pub, decides to take a shortcut through Alan’s yard and falls into the

grave. He breaks his leg. What is the standard of care for Alan toward Felix or

other infrequent trespassers? If Alan has no insurance for this accident, would

the law make Alan responsible?

3. Atlantic Cement owns and operates a cement plant in New York State. Nearby

residents are exposed to noise, soot, and dust and have experienced lowered

property values as a result of Atlantic Cement’s operations. Is there a

common-law remedy for nearby property owners for losses occasioned by

Atlantic’s operations? If so, what is it called?

[1] Rowland v. Christian, 443 P.2d 561 (Cal. 1968).

[2] Norris v. Williams, 54 A.2d 331 (Md. 1947).

[3] Shelley v. Kraemer, 334 U.S. 1 (1947).

[4] Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff, 467 U.S. 229 (1984).

[5] Kelo v. New London, 545 U.S. 469 (2005).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1140

24.5 Environmental Law

LEARNING OBJECTIVES

1. Describe the major federal laws that govern business activities that may

adversely affect air quality and water quality.

2. Describe the major federal laws that govern waste disposal and chemical

hazards including pesticides.

In one sense, environmental law is very old. Medieval England had smoke control laws that established

the seasons when soft coal could be burned. Nuisance laws give private individuals a limited control over

polluting activities of adjacent landowners. But a comprehensive set of US laws directed toward general

protection of the environment is largely a product of the past quarter-century, with most of the legislative

activity stemming from the late 1960s and later, when people began to perceive that the environment was

systematically deteriorating from assaults by rapid population growth and greatly increased automobile

driving, vast proliferation of factories that generate waste products, and a sharp rise in the production of

toxic materials. Two of the most significant developments in environmental law came in 1970, when the

National Environmental Policy Act took effect and the Environmental Protection Agency became the first

of a number of new federal administrative agencies to be established during the decade.

National Environmental Policy Act
Signed into law by President Nixon on January 1, 1970, the National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA)

declared that it shall be the policy of the federal government, in cooperation with state and local

governments, “to create and maintain conditions under which man and nature can exist in productive

harmony, and fulfill the social, economic, and other requirements of present and future generations of

Americans

.…

The Congress recognizes that each person should enjoy a healthful environment and that

each person has a responsibility to contribute to the preservation and enhancement of the

environment.”[1]

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1141

The most significant aspect of NEPA is its requirement that federal agencies prepare

an environmental impact statement in every recommendation or report on proposals for legislation

and whenever undertaking a major federal action that significantly affects environmental quality. The

statement must (1) detail the environmental impact of the proposed action, (2) list any unavoidable

adverse impacts should the action be taken, (3) consider alternatives to the proposed action, (4) compare

short-term and long-term consequences, and (5) describe irreversible commitments of resources. Unless

the impact statement is prepared, the project can be enjoined from proceeding. Note that NEPA does not

apply to purely private activities but only to those proposed to be carried out in some manner by federal

agencies.

Environmental Protection Agency
The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) has been in the forefront of the news since its creation in

1970. Charged with monitoring environmental practices of industry, assisting the government and private

business to halt environmental deterioration, promulgating regulations consistent with federal

environmental policy, and policing industry for violations of the various federal environmental statutes

and regulations, the EPA has had a pervasive influence on American business. Business Week noted the

following in 1977: “Cars rolling off Detroit’s assembly line now have antipollution devices as standard

equipment. The dense black smokestack emissions that used to symbolize industrial prosperity are rare,

and illegal, sights. Plants that once blithely ran discharge water out of a pipe and into a river must apply

for permits that are almost impossible to get unless the plants install expensive water treatment

equipment. All told, the EPA has made a sizable dent in man-made environmental filth.” [2]

The EPA is especially active in regulating water and air pollution and in overseeing the disposition of toxic

wastes and chemicals. To these problems we now turn.

Water Pollution
Clean Water Act

Legislation governing the nation’s waterways goes back a long time. The first federal water pollution

statute was the Rivers and Harbors Act of 1899. Congress enacted new laws in 1948, 1956, 1965, 1966, and

1970. But the centerpiece of water pollution enforcement is the Clean Water Act of 1972 (technically, the

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1142

Federal Water Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972), as amended in 1977 and by the Water Quality

Act of 1987. The Clean Water Act is designed to restore and maintain the “chemical, physical, and

biological integrity of the Nation’s waters.”[3] It operates on the states, requiring them to designate the

uses of every significant body of water within their borders (e.g., for drinking water, recreation,

commercial fishing) and to set water quality standards to reduce pollution to levels appropriate for each

use.

Congress only has power to regulate interstate commerce, and so the Clean Water Act is applicable only to

“navigable waters” of the United States. This has led to disputes over whether the act can apply, say, to an

abandoned gravel pit that has no visible connection to navigable waterways, even if the gravel pit provides

habitat for migratory birds. In Solid Waste Agency of Northern Cook County v. Army Corps of

Engineers, the US Supreme Court said no. [4]

Private Industry

The Clean Water Act also governs private industry and imposes stringent standards on the discharge of

pollutants into waterways and publicly owned sewage systems. The act created an effluent permit system

known as the National Pollutant Discharge Elimination System. To discharge any pollutants into

navigable waters from a “point source” like a pipe, ditch, ship, or container, a company must obtain a

certification that it meets specified standards, which are continually being tightened. For example, until

1983, industry had to use the “best practicable technology” currently available, but after July 1, 1984, it

had to use the “best available technology” economically achievable. Companies must limit certain kinds of

“conventional pollutants” (such as suspended solids and acidity) by “best conventional control

technology.”

Other EPA Water Activities

Federal law governs, and the EPA regulates, a number of other water control measures. Ocean dumping,

for example, is the subject of the Marine Protection, Research, and Sanctuaries Act of 1972, which gives

the EPA jurisdiction over wastes discharged into the oceans. The Clean Water Act gives the EPA and the

US Army Corps of Engineers authority to protect waters, marshlands, and other wetlands against

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1143

degradation caused by dredging and fills. The EPA also oversees state and local plans for restoring general

water quality to acceptable levels in the face of a host of non-point-source pollution. The Clean Water Act

controls municipal sewage systems, which must ensure that wastewater is chemically treated before being

discharged from the sewage system.

Obviously, of critical importance to the nation’s health is the supply of drinking water. To ensure its

continuing purity, Congress enacted the Safe Drinking Water Act of 1974, with amendments passed in

1986 and 1996. This act aims to protect water at its sources: rivers, lakes, reservoirs, springs, and

groundwater wells. (The act does not regulate private wells that serve fewer than twenty-five individuals.)

This law has two strategies for combating pollution of drinking water. It establishes national standards for

drinking water derived from both surface reservoirs and underground aquifers. It also authorizes the EPA

to regulate the injection of solid wastes into deep wells (as happens, for instance, by leakage from

underground storage tanks).

Air Pollution
The centerpiece of the legislative effort to clean the atmosphere is the Clean Air Act of 1970 (amended in

1975, 1977, and 1990). Under this act, the EPA has set two levels of National Ambient Air Quality

Standards (NAAQS). The primary standards limit the ambient (i.e., circulating) pollution that affects

human health; secondary standards limit pollution that affects animals, plants, and property. The heart of

the Clean Air Act is the requirement that subject to EPA approval, the states implement the standards that

the EPA establishes. The setting of these pollutant standards was coupled with directing the states to

develop state implementation plans (SIPs), applicable to appropriate industrial sources in the state, in

order to achieve these standards. The act was amended in 1977 and 1990 primarily to set new goals

(dates) for achieving attainment of NAAQS since many areas of the country had failed to meet the

deadlines.

Beyond the NAAQS, the EPA has established several specific standards to control different types of air

pollution. One major type is pollution that mobile sources, mainly automobiles, emit. The EPA requires

new cars to be equipped with catalytic converters and to use unleaded gasoline to eliminate the most

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1144

noxious fumes and to keep them from escaping into the atmosphere. To minimize pollution from

stationary sources, the EPA also imposes uniform standards on new industrial plants and those that have

been substantially modernized. And to safeguard against emissions from older plants, states must

promulgate and enforce SIPs.

The Clean Air Act is even more solicitous of air quality in certain parts of the nation, such as designated

wilderness areas and national parks. For these areas, the EPA has set standards to prevent significant

deterioration in order to keep the air as pristine and clear as it was centuries ago.

The EPA also worries about chemicals so toxic that the tiniest quantities could prove fatal or extremely

hazardous to health. To control emission of substances like asbestos, beryllium, mercury, vinyl chloride,

benzene, and arsenic, the EPA has established or proposed various National Emissions Standards for

Hazardous Air Pollutants.

Concern over acid rain and other types of air pollution prompted Congress to add almost eight hundred

pages of amendments to the Clean Air Act in 1990. (The original act was fifty pages long.) As a result of

these amendments, the act was modernized in a manner that parallels other environmental laws. For

instance, the amendments established a permit system that is modeled after the Clean Water Act. And the

amendments provide for felony convictions for willful violations, similar to penalties incorporated into

other statutes.

The amendments include certain defenses for industry. Most important, companies are protected from

allegations that they are violating the law by showing that they were acting in accordance with a permit. In

addition to this “permit shield,” the law also contains protection for workers who unintentionally violate

the law while following their employers’ instructions.

Waste Disposal
Though pollution of the air by highly toxic substances like benzene or vinyl chloride may seem a problem

removed from that of the ordinary person, we are all in fact polluters. Every year, the United States

generates approximately 230 million tons of “trash”—about 4.6 pounds per person per day. Less than

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1145

one-quarter of it is recycled; the rest is incinerated or buried in landfills. But many of the country’s

landfills have been closed, either because they were full or because they were contaminating groundwater.

Once groundwater is contaminated, it is extremely expensive and difficult to clean it up. In the 1965 Solid

Waste Disposal Act and the 1970 Resource Recovery Act, Congress sought to regulate the discharge of

garbage by encouraging waste management and recycling. Federal grants were available for research and

training, but the major regulatory effort was expected to come from the states and municipalities.

But shocking news prompted Congress to get tough in 1976. The plight of homeowners near Love Canal in

upstate New York became a major national story as the discovery of massive underground leaks of toxic

chemicals buried during the previous quarter century led to evacuation of hundreds of homes. Next came

the revelation that Kepone, an exceedingly toxic pesticide, had been dumped into the James River in

Virginia, causing a major human health hazard and severe damage to fisheries in the James and

downstream in the Chesapeake Bay. The rarely discussed industrial dumping of hazardous wastes now

became an open controversy, and Congress responded in 1976 with the Resource Conservation and

Recovery Act (RCRA) and the Toxic Substances Control Act (TSCA) and in 1980 with the Comprehensive

Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act (CERCLA).

Resource Conservation and Recovery Act

The RCRA expresses a “cradle-to-grave” philosophy: hazardous wastes must be regulated at every stage.

The act gives the EPA power to govern their creation, storage, transport, treatment, and disposal. Any

person or company that generates hazardous waste must obtain a permit (known as a “manifest”) either

to store it on its own site or ship it to an EPA-approved treatment, storage, or disposal facility. No longer

can hazardous substances simply be dumped at a convenient landfill. Owners and operators of such sites

must show that they can pay for damage growing out of their operations, and even after the sites are

closed to further dumping, they must set aside funds to monitor and maintain the sites safely.

This philosophy can be severe. In 1986, the Supreme Court ruled that bankruptcy is not a sufficient reason

for a company to abandon toxic waste dumps if state regulations reasonably require protection in the

interest of public health or safety. The practical effect of the ruling is that trustees of the bankrupt

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1146

company must first devote assets to cleaning up a dump site, and only from remaining assets may they

satisfy creditors. [5] Another severity is RCRA’s imposition of criminal liability, including fines of up to

$25,000 a day and one-year prison sentences, which can be extended beyond owners to individual

employees, as discussed in U.S. v. Johnson & Towers, Inc., et al., (seeSection 24.6.2 “Criminal Liability of

Employees under RCRA”).

Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act

The CERCLA, also known as the Superfund, gives the EPA emergency powers to respond to public health

or environmental dangers from faulty hazardous waste disposal, currently estimated to occur at more

than seventeen thousand sites around the country. The EPA can direct immediate removal of wastes

presenting imminent danger (e.g., from train wrecks, oil spills, leaking barrels, and fires). Injuries can be

sudden and devastating; in 1979, for example, when a freight train derailed in Florida, ninety thousand

pounds of chlorine gas escaped from a punctured tank car, leaving 8 motorists dead and 183 others

injured and forcing 3,500 residents within a 7-mile radius to be evacuated. The EPA may also carry out

“planned removals” when the danger is substantial, even if immediate removal is not necessary.

The EPA prods owners who can be located to voluntarily clean up sites they have abandoned. But if the

owners refuse, the EPA and the states will undertake the task, drawing on a federal trust fund financed

mainly by taxes on the manufacture or import of certain chemicals and petroleum (the balance of the fund

comes from general revenues). States must finance 10 percent of the cost of cleaning up private sites and

50 percent of the cost of cleaning up public facilities. The EPA and the states can then assess unwilling

owners’ punitive damages up to triple the cleanup costs.

Cleanup requirements are especially controversial when applied to landowners who innocently purchased

contaminated property. To deal with this problem, Congress enacted the Superfund Amendment and

Reauthorization Act in 1986, which protects innocent landowners who—at the time of purchase—made an

“appropriate inquiry” into the prior uses of the property. The act also requires companies to publicly

disclose information about hazardous chemicals they use. We now turn to other laws regulating chemical

hazards.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1147

Chemical Hazards
Toxic Substances Control Act

Chemical substances that decades ago promised to improve the quality of life have lately shown their

negative side—they have serious adverse side effects. For example, asbestos, in use for half a century,

causes cancer and asbestosis, a debilitating lung disease, in workers who breathed in fibers decades ago.

The result has been crippling disease and death and more than thirty thousand asbestos-related lawsuits

filed nationwide. Other substances, such as polychlorinated biphenyls (PCBs) and dioxin, have caused

similar tragedy. Together, the devastating effects of chemicals led to enactment of the TSCA, designed to

control the manufacture, processing, commercial distribution, use, and disposal of chemicals that pose

unreasonable health or environmental risks. (The TSCA does not apply to pesticides, tobacco, nuclear

materials, firearms and ammunition, food, food additives, drugs, and cosmetics—all are regulated by

other federal laws.)

The TSCA gives the EPA authority to screen for health and environmental risks by requiring companies to

notify the EPA ninety days before manufacturing or importing new chemicals. The EPA may demand that

the companies test the substances before marketing them and may regulate them in a number of ways,

such as requiring the manufacturer to label its products, to keep records on its manufacturing and

disposal processes, and to document all significant adverse reactions in people exposed to the chemicals.

The EPA also has authority to ban certain especially hazardous substances, and it has banned the further

production of PCBs and many uses of asbestos.

Both industry groups and consumer groups have attacked the TSCA. Industry groups criticize the act

because the enforcement mechanism requires mountainous paperwork and leads to widespread delay.

Consumer groups complain because the EPA has been slow to act against numerous chemical substances.

The debate continues.

Pesticide Regulation

The United States is a major user of pesticides, substances that eliminate troublesome insects, rodents,

fungi, and bacteria, consuming more than a billion pounds a year in the form of thirty-five thousand

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1148

separate chemicals. As useful as they can be, like many chemical substances, pesticides can have serious

side effects on humans and plant and animal life. Beginning in the early 1970s, Congress enacted major

amendments to the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act of 1947 and the Federal Food,

Drug, and Cosmetic Act (FFDCA) of 1906.

These laws direct the EPA to determine whether pesticides properly balance effectiveness against safety. If

the pesticide can carry out its intended function without causing unreasonable adverse effects on human

health or the environment, it may remain on the market. Otherwise, the EPA has authority to regulate or

even ban its distribution and use. To enable the EPA to carry out its functions, the laws require

manufacturers to provide a wealth of data about the way individual pesticides work and their side effects.

The EPA is required to inspect pesticides to ensure that they conform to their labeled purposes, content,

and safety, and the agency is empowered to certify pesticides for either general or restricted use. If a

pesticide is restricted, only those persons certified in approved training programs may use it. Likewise,

under the Pesticide Amendment to the FFDCA, the EPA must establish specific tolerances for the residue

of pesticides on feed crops and both raw and processed foods. The Food and Drug Administration (for

agricultural commodities) and the US Department of Agriculture (for meat, poultry, and fish products)

enforce these provisions.

Other Types of Environmental Controls
Noise Regulation

Under the Noise Regulation Act of 1972, Congress has attempted to combat a growing menace to US

workers, residents, and consumers. People who live close to airports and major highways, workers who

use certain kinds of machinery (e.g., air compressors, rock drills, bulldozers), and consumers who use

certain products, such as power mowers and air conditioners, often suffer from a variety of ailments. The

Noise Regulation Act delegates to the EPA power to limit “noise emissions” from these major sources of

noise. Under the act, manufacturers may not sell new products that fail to conform to the noise standards

the EPA sets, and users are forbidden from dismantling noise control devices installed on these products.

Moreover, manufacturers must label noisy products properly. Private suits may be filed against violators,

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1149

and the act also permits fines of up to $25,000 per day and a year in jail for those who seek to avoid its

terms.

Radiation Controls

The terrifying effects of a nuclear disaster became frighteningly clear when the Soviet Union’s nuclear

power plant at Chernobyl exploded in early 1986, discharging vast quantities of radiation into the world’s

airstream and affecting people thousands of miles away. In the United States, the most notorious nuclear

accident occurred at the Three Mile Island nuclear utility in Pennsylvania in 1979, crippling the facility for

years because of the extreme danger and long life of the radiation. Primary responsibility for overseeing

nuclear safety rests with the Nuclear Regulatory Commission, but many other agencies and several federal

laws (including the Clean Air Act; the Federal Water Pollution Control Act; the Safe Drinking Water Act;

the Uranium Mill Tailings Radiation Control Act; the Marine Protection, Research, and Sanctuaries Act;

the Nuclear Waste Policy Act of 1982; the CERCLA; and the Ocean Dumping Act) govern the use of

nuclear materials and the storage of radioactive wastes (some of which will remain severely dangerous for

thousands of years). Through many of these laws, the EPA has been assigned the responsibility of setting

radiation guidelines, assessing new technology, monitoring radiation in the environment, setting limits on

release of radiation from nuclear utilities, developing guidance for use of X-rays in medicine, and helping

to plan for radiation emergencies.

KEY TAKEAWAY

Laws limiting the use of one’s property have been around for many years;

common-law restraints (e.g., the law of nuisance) exist as causes of action against

those who would use their property to adversely affect the life or health of others

or the value of their neighbors’ property. Since the 1960s, extensive federal laws

governing the environment have been enacted. These include laws governing air,

water, chemicals, pesticides, solid waste, and nuclear activities. Some laws include

criminal penalties for noncompliance.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1150

EXERCISES

1. Who is responsible for funding CERCLA? That is, what is the source of funds

for cleanups of hazardous waste?

2. Why is it necessary to have criminal penalties for noncompliance with

environmental laws?

3. What is the role of states in setting standards for clean air and clean water?

4. Which federal act sets up a “cradle-to-grave” system for handling waste?

5. Why are federal environmental laws necessary? Why not let the states

exclusively govern in the area of environmental protection?

[1] 42 United States Code, Section 4321 et seq.

[2] “The Tricks of the Trade-off,” Business Week, April 4, 1977, 72.

[3] 33 United States Code, Section 1251.

[4] Solid Waste Agency of Northern Cook County v. Army Corps of Engineers, 531 U.S. 159

(2001).

[5] Midlantic National Bank v. New Jersey, 474 U.S. 494 (1986).

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1151

24.6 Cases
Reasonable Use Doctrine
Hoover v. Crane

362 Mich. 36, 106 N.W.2d 563 (1960)

EDWARDS, JUSTICE

This appeal represents a controversy between plaintiff cottage and resort owners on an inland Michigan

lake and defendant, a farmer with a fruit orchard, who was using the lake water for irrigation. The

chancellor who heard the matter ruled that defendant had a right to reasonable use of lake water. The

decree defined such reasonable use in terms which were unsatisfactory to plaintiffs who have appealed.

The testimony taken before the chancellor pertained to the situation at Hutchins Lake, in Allegan county,

during the summer of 1958. Defendant is a fruit farmer who owns a 180-acre farm abutting on the lake.

Hutchins Lake has an area of 350 acres in a normal season. Seventy-five cottages and several farms,

including defendant’s, abut on it. Defendant’s frontage is approximately 1/4 mile, or about 10% of the

frontage of the lake.

Hutchins Lake is spring fed. It has no inlet but does have an outlet which drains south. Frequently in the

summertime the water level falls so that the flow at the outlet ceases.

All witnesses agreed that the summer of 1958 was exceedingly dry and plaintiffs’ witnesses testified that

Hutchins Lake’s level was the lowest it had ever been in their memory. Early in August, defendant began

irrigation of his 50-acre pear orchard by pumping water out of Hutchins Lake. During that month the lake

level fell 6 to 8 inches—the water line receded 50 to 60 feet and cottagers experienced severe difficulties

with boating and swimming.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1152

* * *

The tenor of plaintiffs’ testimony was to attribute the 6- to 8-inch drop in the Hutchins Lake level in that

summer to defendant’s irrigation activities. Defendant contended that the decrease was due to natural

causes, that the irrigation was of great benefit to him and contributed only slightly to plaintiff’s

discomfiture. He suggests to us:

One could fairly say that because plaintiffs couldn’t grapple with the unknown causes that admittedly

occasioned a greater part of the injury complained of, they chose to grapple mightily with the defendant

because he is known and visible.

The circuit judge found it impossible to determine a normal lake level from the testimony, except that the

normal summer level of the lake is lower than the level at which the lake ceases to drain into the outlet. He

apparently felt that plaintiffs’ problems were due much more to the abnormal weather conditions of the

summer of 1958 than to defendant’s irrigation activities.

His opinion concluded:

Accepting the reasonable use theory advanced by plaintiffs it appears to the court that the most equitable

disposition of this case would be to allow defendant to use water from the lake until such time when his

use interferes with the normal use of his neighbors. One quarter inch of water from the lake ought not to

interfere with the rights and uses of defendant’s neighbors and this quantity of water ought to be

sufficient in time of need to service 45 acres of pears. A meter at the pump, sealed if need be, ought to be a

sufficient safeguard. Pumping should not be permitted between the hours of 11 p.m. and 7 a.m. Water

need be metered only at such times as there is no drainage into the outlet.

The decree in this suit may provide that the case be kept open for the submission of future petitions and

proofs as the conditions permit or require.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1153

* * *

Michigan has adopted the reasonable-use rule in determining the conflicting rights of riparian owners to

the use of lake water.

In 1874, Justice COOLEY said:

It is therefore not a diminution in the quantity of the water alone, or an alteration in its flow, or either or

both of these circumstances combined with injury, that will give a right of action, if in view of all the

circumstances, and having regard to equality of right in others, that which has been done and which

causes the injury is not unreasonable. In other words, the injury that is incidental to a reasonable

enjoyment of the common right can demand no redress. Dumont v. Kellogg, 29 Mich 420, 425.

And in People v. Hulbert, the Court said:

No statement can be made as to what is such reasonable use which will, without variation or qualification,

apply to the facts of every case. But in determining whether a use is reasonable we must consider what the

use is for; its extent, duration, necessity, and its application; the nature and size of the stream, and the

several uses to which it is put; the extent of the injury to the one proprietor and of the benefit to the other;

and all other facts which may bear upon the reasonableness of the use. Red River Roller Mills v. Wright,

30 Minn 249, 15 NW 167, and cases cited.

The Michigan view is in general accord with 4 Restatement, Torts, §§ 851–853.

* * *

We interpret the circuit judge’s decree as affording defendant the total metered equivalent in pumpage of

1/4 inch of the content of Hutchins Lake to be used in any dry period in between the cessation of flow

from the outlet and the date when such flow recommences. Where the decree also provides for the case to

be kept open for future petitions based on changed conditions, it would seem to afford as much protection

for plaintiffs as to the future as this record warrants.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1154

Both resort use and agricultural use of the lake are entirely legitimate purposes. Neither serves to remove

water from the watershed. There is, however, no doubt that the irrigation use does occasion some water

loss due to increased evaporation and absorption. Indeed, extensive irrigation might constitute a threat to

the very existence of the lake in which all riparian owners have a stake; and at some point the use of the

water which causes loss must yield to the common good.

The question on this appeal is, of course, whether the chancellor’s determination of this point was

unreasonable as to plaintiffs. On this record, we cannot overrule the circuit judge’s view that most of

plaintiffs’ 1958 plight was due to natural causes. Nor can we say, if this be the only irrigation use intended

and the only water diversion sought, that use of the amount provided in the decree during the dry season

is unreasonable in respect to other riparian owners.

Affirmed.

CASE QUESTIONS

1. If the defendant has caused a diminution in water flow, an alteration of the water

flow, and the plaintiff is adversely affected, why would the Supreme Court of

Michigan not provide some remedy?

2. Is it possible to define an injury that is “not unreasonable”?

3. Would the case even have been brought if there had not been a drought?

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1155

Criminal Liability of Employees under RCRA
U.S. v. Johnson & Towers, Inc., Jack W. Hopkins, and Peter Angel

741 F.2d 662 (1984)

SLOVITER, Circuit Judge

Before us is the government’s appeal from the dismissal of three counts of an indictment charging

unlawful disposal of hazardous wastes under the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act. In a question

of first impression regarding the statutory definition of “person,” the district court concluded that the

Act’s criminal penalty provision imposing fines and imprisonment could not apply to the individual

defendants. We will reverse.

The criminal prosecution in this case arose from the disposal of chemicals at a plant owned by Johnson &

Towers in Mount Laurel, New Jersey. In its operations the company, which repairs and overhauls large

motor vehicles, uses degreasers and other industrial chemicals that contain chemicals such as methylene

chloride and trichlorethylene, classified as “hazardous wastes” under the Resource Conservation and

Recovery Act (RCRA), 42 U.S.C. §§ 6901–6987 (1982) and “pollutants” under the Clean Water Act, 33

U.S.C. §§ 1251–1376 (1982). During the period relevant here, the waste chemicals from cleaning

operations were drained into a holding tank and, when the tank was full, pumped into a trench. The

trench flowed from the plant property into Parker’s Creek, a tributary of the Delaware River. Under

RCRA, generators of such wastes must obtain a permit for disposal from the Environmental Protection

Agency (E.P.A.). The E.P.A. had neither issued nor received an application for a permit for Johnson &

Towers’ operations.

The indictment named as defendants Johnson & Towers and two of its employees, Jack Hopkins, a

foreman, and Peter Angel, the service manager in the trucking department. According to the indictment,

over a three-day period federal agents saw workers pump waste from the tank into the trench, and on the

third day observed toxic chemicals flowing into the creek.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1156

Count 1 of the indictment charged all three defendants with conspiracy under 18 U.S.C. § 371 (1982).

Counts 2, 3, and 4 alleged violations under the RCRA criminal provision, 42 U.S.C. § 6928(d) (1982).

Count 5 alleged a violation of the criminal provision of the Clean Water Act, 33 U.S.C. § 1319(c) (1982).

Each substantive count also charged the individual defendants as aiders and abettors under 18 U.S.C. § 2

(1982).

The counts under RCRA charged that the defendants “did knowingly treat, store, and dispose of, and did

cause to be treated, stored and disposed of hazardous wastes without having obtained a permit…in that

the defendants discharged, deposited, injected, dumped, spilled, leaked and placed degreasers…into the

trench.…” The indictment alleged that both Angel and Hopkins “managed, supervised and directed a

substantial portion of Johnson & Towers’ operations…including those related to the treatment, storage

and disposal of the hazardous wastes and pollutants” and that the chemicals were discharged by “the

defendants and others at their direction.” The indictment did not otherwise detail Hopkins’ and Angel’s

activities or responsibilities.

Johnson & Towers pled guilty to the RCRA counts. Hopkins and Angel pled not guilty, and then moved to

dismiss counts 2, 3, and 4. The court concluded that the RCRA criminal provision applies only to “owners

and operators,” i.e., those obligated under the statute to obtain a permit. Since neither Hopkins nor Angel

was an “owner” or “operator,” the district court granted the motion as to the RCRA charges but held that

the individuals could be liable on these three counts under 18 U.S.C. § 2 for aiding and abetting. The court

denied the government’s motion for reconsideration, and the government appealed to this court under 18

U.S.C. § 3731 (1982).

* * *

The single issue in this appeal is whether the individual defendants are subject to prosecution under

RCRA’s criminal provision, which applies to:

any person who—

.…

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1157

(2) knowingly treats, stores, or disposes of any hazardous waste identified or listed under this subchapter

either—

(A) without having obtained a permit under section 6925 of this title…or

(B) in knowing violation of any material condition or requirement of such permit.

42 U.S.C. § 6928(d) (emphasis added). The permit provision in section 6925, referred to in section

6928(d), requires “each person owning or operating a facility for the treatment, storage, or disposal of

hazardous waste identified or listed under this subchapter to have a permit” from the E.P.A.

The parties offer contrary interpretations of section 6928(d)(2)(A). Defendants consider it an

administrative enforcement mechanism, applying only to those who come within section 6925 and fail to

comply; the government reads it as penalizing anyone who handles hazardous waste without a permit or

in violation of a permit. Neither party has cited another case, nor have we found one, considering the

application of this criminal provision to an individual other than an owner or operator.

As in any statutory analysis, we are obliged first to look to the language and then, if needed, attempt to

divine Congress’ specific intent with respect to the issue.

First, “person” is defined in the statute as “an individual, trust, firm, joint stock company, corporation

(including a government corporation), partnership, association, State, municipality, commission, political

subdivision of a State, or any interstate body.” 42 U.S.C. § 6903(15) (1982). Had Congress meant in

section 6928(d)(2)(A) to take aim more narrowly, it could have used more narrow language. Since it did

not, we attribute to “any person” the definition given the term in section 6903(15).

Second, under the plain language of the statute the only explicit basis for exoneration is the existence of a

permit covering the action. Nothing in the language of the statute suggests that we should infer another

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1158

provision exonerating persons who knowingly treat, store or dispose of hazardous waste but are not

owners or operators.

Finally, though the result may appear harsh, it is well established that criminal penalties attached to

regulatory statutes intended to protect public health, in contrast to statutes based on common law crimes,

are to be construed to effectuate the regulatory purpose.

* * *

Congress enacted RCRA in 1976 as a “cradle-to-grave” regulatory scheme for toxic materials, providing

“nationwide protection against the dangers of improper hazardous waste disposal.” H.R. Rep. No. 1491,

94th Cong., 2d Sess. 11, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News 6238, 6249. RCRA was enacted to

provide “a multifaceted approach toward solving the problems associated with the 3–4 billion tons of

discarded materials generated each year, and the problems resulting from the anticipated 8% annual

increase in the volume of such waste.” Id. at 2, 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 6239. The committee

reports accompanying legislative consideration of RCRA contain numerous statements evincing the

Congressional view that improper disposal of toxic materials was a serious national problem.

The original statute made knowing disposal (but not treatment or storage) of such waste without a permit

a misdemeanor. Amendments in 1978 and 1980 expanded the criminal provision to cover treatment and

storage and made violation of section 6928 a felony. The fact that Congress amended the statute twice to

broaden the scope of its substantive provisions and enhance the penalty is a strong indication of Congress’

increasing concern about the seriousness of the prohibited conduct.

We conclude that in RCRA, no less than in the Food and Drugs Act, Congress endeavored to control

hazards that, “in the circumstances of modern industrialism, are largely beyond self-protection.” United

States v. Dotterweich, 320 U.S. at 280. It would undercut the purposes of the legislation to limit the class

of potential defendants to owners and operators when others also bear responsibility for handling

regulated materials. The phrase “without having obtained a permitunder section 6925” (emphasis added)

merely references the section under which the permit is required and exempts from prosecution under

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1159

section 6928(d)(2)(A) anyone who has obtained a permit; we conclude that it has no other limiting effect.

Therefore we reject the district court’s construction limiting the substantive criminal provision by

confining “any person” in section 6928(d)(2)(A) to owners and operators of facilities that store, treat or

dispose of hazardous waste, as an unduly narrow view of both the statutory language and the

congressional intent.

CASE QUESTIONS

1. The district court (trial court) accepted the individual defendants’ argument. What

was that argument?

2. On what reasoning did the appellate court reject that argument?

3. If employees of a company that is violating the RCRA carry out disposal of hazardous

substances in violation of the RCRA, they would presumably lose their jobs if they

didn’t. What is the moral justification for applying criminal penalties to such

employees (such as Hopkins and Angel)?

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1160

24.7 Summary and Exercises

Summary
An estate is an interest in real property; it is the degree to which a thing is owned. Freehold estates are

those with an uncertain duration; leaseholds are estates due to expire at a definite time. A present estate is

one that is currently owned; a future estate is one that is owned now but not yet available for use.

Present estates are (1) the fee simple absolute; (2) the fee simple defeasible, which itself may be divided

into three types, and (3) the life estate.

Future estates are generally of two types: reversion and remainder. A reversion arises whenever a

transferred estate will endure for a shorter time than that originally owned by the transferor. A remainder

interest arises when the transferor gives the reversion interest to someone else.

Use of air, earth, and water are the major rights incident to ownership of real property. Traditionally, the

owner held “up to the sky” and “down to the depths,” but these rules have been modified to balance

competing rights in a modern economy. The law governing water rights varies with the states; in general,

the eastern states with more plentiful water have adopted either the natural flow doctrine or the

reasonable use doctrine of riparian rights, giving those who live along a waterway certain rights to use the

water. By contrast, western states have tended to apply the prior appropriation doctrine, which holds that

first in time is first in right, even if those downstream are disadvantaged.

An easement is an interest in land—created by express agreement, prior use, or necessity—that permits

one person to make use of another’s estate. An affirmative easement gives one person the right to use

another’s land; a negative easement prevents the owner from using his land in a way that will affect

another person’s land. In understanding easement law, the important distinctions are between easements

appurtenant and in gross, and between dominant and servient owners.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1161

The law not only defines the nature of the property interest but also regulates land use. Tort law regulates

land use by imposing liability for (1) activities that affect those off the land and (2) injuries caused to

people who enter it. The two most important theories relating to the former are nuisance and trespass.

With respect to the latter, the common law confusingly distinguishes among trespassers, licensees, and

invitees. Some states are moving away from the perplexing and rigid rules of the past and simply require

owners to maintain their property in a reasonably safe condition.

Land use may also be regulated by private agreement through the restrictive covenant, an agreement that

“runs with the land” and that will be binding on any subsequent owner. Land use is also regulated by the

government’s power under eminent domain to take private land for public purposes (upon payment of

just compensation), through zoning laws, and through recently enacted environmental statutes, including

the National Environmental Policy Act and laws governing air, water, treatment of hazardous wastes, and

chemicals.

EXERCISES

1. Dorothy deeded an acre of real estate that she owns to George for the life of

Benny and then to Ernie. Describe the property interests of George, Benny, Ernie,

and Dorothy.

2. In Exercise 1, assume that George moves into a house on the property. During a

tornado, the roof is destroyed and a window is smashed. Who is responsible for

repairing the roof and window? Why?

3. Dennis likes to spend his weekends in his backyard, shooting his rifle across his

neighbor’s yard. If Dennis never sets foot on his neighbor’s property, and if the

bullets strike neither persons nor property, has he violated the legal rights of the

neighbor? Explain.

4. Dennis also drills an oil well in his backyard. He “slant drills” the well; that is, the

well slants from a point on the surface in his yard to a point four hundred feet

beneath the surface of his neighbor’s yard. Dennis has slanted the drilling in order

to capture his neighbor’s oil. Can he do this legally? Explain.

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1162

5. Wanda is in charge of acquisitions for her company. Realizing that water is

important to company operations, Wanda buys a plant site on a river, and the

company builds a plant that uses all of the river water. Downstream owners bring

suit to stop the company from using any water. What is the result? Why?

6. Sunny decides to build a solar home. Before beginning construction, she wants to

establish the legal right to prevent her neighbors from constructing buildings that

will block the sunlight. She has heard that the law distinguishes between licenses

and easements, easements appurtenant and in gross, and affirmative and negative

easements. Which of these interests would you recommend for Sunny? Why?

SELF-TEST QUESTIONS

1. A freehold estate is defined as an estate

a. with an uncertain duration

b. due to expire at a definite time

c. owned now but not yet available for use

d. that is leased or rented

A fee simple defeasible is a type of

a. present estate

b. future estate

c. life estate

d. leasehold estate

A reversion is

a. a present estate that prevents transfer of land out of the family

b. a form of life estate

c. a future estate that arises when the estate transferred has a

duration less than that originally owned by the transferor

d. identical to a remainder interest

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books Saylor.org
1163

An easement is an interest in land that may be created by

a. express agreement

b. prior use

c. necessity

d. all of the above

The prior appropriation doctrine

a. tends to be applied by eastern states

b. holds that first in time is first in right

c. gives those that live along a waterway special rights to use the

water

d. all of the above

SELF-TEST ANSWERS

1. a

2. a

3. c

4. d

5. b

Still stressed with your coursework?
Get quality coursework help from an expert!